全文获取类型
收费全文 | 557篇 |
免费 | 18篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 71篇 |
工业经济 | 29篇 |
计划管理 | 91篇 |
经济学 | 187篇 |
综合类 | 1篇 |
运输经济 | 4篇 |
旅游经济 | 4篇 |
贸易经济 | 125篇 |
农业经济 | 19篇 |
经济概况 | 32篇 |
邮电经济 | 12篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 2篇 |
2023年 | 4篇 |
2022年 | 2篇 |
2021年 | 3篇 |
2020年 | 6篇 |
2019年 | 14篇 |
2018年 | 14篇 |
2017年 | 27篇 |
2016年 | 22篇 |
2015年 | 15篇 |
2014年 | 27篇 |
2013年 | 53篇 |
2012年 | 30篇 |
2011年 | 26篇 |
2010年 | 25篇 |
2009年 | 32篇 |
2008年 | 22篇 |
2007年 | 25篇 |
2006年 | 25篇 |
2005年 | 17篇 |
2004年 | 13篇 |
2003年 | 13篇 |
2002年 | 18篇 |
2001年 | 12篇 |
2000年 | 12篇 |
1999年 | 13篇 |
1998年 | 8篇 |
1997年 | 11篇 |
1996年 | 6篇 |
1995年 | 5篇 |
1994年 | 3篇 |
1993年 | 5篇 |
1992年 | 5篇 |
1991年 | 6篇 |
1989年 | 3篇 |
1988年 | 3篇 |
1986年 | 2篇 |
1985年 | 3篇 |
1984年 | 4篇 |
1983年 | 11篇 |
1982年 | 3篇 |
1981年 | 2篇 |
1979年 | 3篇 |
1978年 | 4篇 |
1977年 | 4篇 |
1976年 | 3篇 |
1966年 | 1篇 |
1965年 | 1篇 |
1964年 | 1篇 |
1956年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有575条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
31.
This study focuses on the labour market performance among second‐generation immigrants in Sweden. One motivation behind the analysis is that it gives insight into the long‐term consequences of immigration. Labour market performance relates the probability of having a job, referred to here as a threshold effect and to the differences in income from work, given that a person is in the market and is referred to as an income from work effect. We have shown that a clear threshold effect of being a second‐generation immigrant exists and that different groups of second‐generation immigrants perform differently in the Swedish labour market. 相似文献
32.
Hedonic pricing with quasi-linear preferences is shown to be equivalent to stable matching with transferable utilities and
a participation constraint, and to an optimal transportation (Monge–Kantorovich) linear programming problem. Optimal assignments
in the latter correspond to stable matchings, and to hedonic equilibria. These assignments are shown to exist in great generality;
their marginal indirect payoffs with respect to agent type are shown to be unique whenever direct payoffs vary smoothly with
type. Under a generalized Spence-Mirrlees condition (also known as a twist condition) the assignments are shown to be unique
and to be pure, meaning the matching is one-to-one outside a negligible set. For smooth problems set on compact, connected type spaces such
as the circle, there is a topological obstruction to purity, but we give a weaker condition still guaranteeing uniqueness
of the stable match. 相似文献
33.
Summary. The requirement that a voting procedure be immune to the strategic withdrawal of a candidate for election can be formalized
in different ways. Dutta, Jackson, and Le Breton (Econometrica, 2001) have recently shown that two formalizations of this candidate stability property are incompatible with some other
desirable properties of voting procedures. This article shows that Grether and Plott's nonbinary generalization of Arrow's
Theorem can be used to provide simple proofs of two of their impossibility theorems.
Received: August 15, 2001; revised version: March 11, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" Parts of this article were previously circulated in somewhat different form in a working paper with the same title
by the second author. We are grateful to Michel Le Breton and an anonymous referee for their comments.
Correspondence to:J.A. Weymark 相似文献
34.
35.
The Human Development Index (HDI) uses GDP per capita to measure “command over resources,” which implicitly makes the strong value judgment that inequality and insecurity do not matter. This paper presents revised estimates of the Index of Economic Well‐Being (IEWB) for the United States, the U.K., Canada, Australia, Germany, Norway and Sweden for the period 1980 to 2001 and demonstrates that replacing an index of the log per capita incomes with our IEWB as the “command over resources” component in the Human Development Index (HDI) affects the level and trend of the HDI, even among affluent nations. Because the IEWB recognizes four dimensions of command over resources (Current effective per capita Consumption flows, Net societal Accumulation of stocks of productive resources, Income Distribution and Economic Security), its use has a particularly large impact where underlying trends in these components diverge (e.g. the U.K. or the United States). 相似文献
36.
Lars E. O. Svensson 《The German Economic Review》2001,2(3):309-312
Seitz and TÃdter argue, counter to Svensson, that the P * model provides a rationale for money-growth targeting. In particular, they argue that 'money growth targeting is a special form of inflation forecast targeting based on a "limited" information set. In contrast to "full information" inflation forecast targeting, money growth targeting is likely to be more robust under changing conditions of the real world'.
However, money-growth targeting is better described as a special case of inflation targeting, namely when money growth is considered to be the only predictor of future inflation. But there is overwhelming empirical evidence that there are not only other, but also better, predictors of future inflation than money growth, which makes inflation-forecast targeting superior to money-growth targeting. Inflation-forecast targeting is indeed more robust (in the sense of using available information and allowing judgemental adjustments in a flexible way) than monetary targeting.
In particular, in the P * model, the real money gap is a better predictor of future inflation than money growth, as demonstrated theoretically by Svensson and empirically by Gerlach and Svensson (the empirical finding is also confirmed by Trecroci and Vega). Therefore, inflation-forecast targeting is superior also within the P * model. Under `changing conditions of the real world', for instance after the formation of a monetary union, money growth is likely to be particularly unreliable as a predictor of future inflation, making monetary targeting especially unsuitable and non-robust. 相似文献
However, money-growth targeting is better described as a special case of inflation targeting, namely when money growth is considered to be the only predictor of future inflation. But there is overwhelming empirical evidence that there are not only other, but also better, predictors of future inflation than money growth, which makes inflation-forecast targeting superior to money-growth targeting. Inflation-forecast targeting is indeed more robust (in the sense of using available information and allowing judgemental adjustments in a flexible way) than monetary targeting.
In particular, in the P * model, the real money gap is a better predictor of future inflation than money growth, as demonstrated theoretically by Svensson and empirically by Gerlach and Svensson (the empirical finding is also confirmed by Trecroci and Vega). Therefore, inflation-forecast targeting is superior also within the P * model. Under `changing conditions of the real world', for instance after the formation of a monetary union, money growth is likely to be particularly unreliable as a predictor of future inflation, making monetary targeting especially unsuitable and non-robust. 相似文献
37.
Trond M.Andersen Lars Thuestad Tom A.Thorstensen 《设备管理与维修》2008,(2):62-63
介绍Statoil公司提出的机会维修概念和它对生产所起的重要作用,举例说明机会维修的可行性,并对机会维修进行优化使它更好地为生产服务. 相似文献
38.
Asset pricing with loss aversion 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
The use of standard preferences for asset pricing has not been very successful in matching asset price characteristics, such as the risk-free interest rate, equity premium and the Sharpe ratio, to time series data. Behavioral finance has recently proposed more realistic preferences such as those with loss aversion. Research is starting to explore the implications of behaviorally founded preferences for asset price characteristics. Encouraged by some studies of Benartzi and Thaler [1995. Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (1), 73–92] and Barberis et al. [2001. Prospect theory and asset prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics CXVI (1), 1–53] we study asset pricing with loss aversion in a production economy. Here, we employ a stochastic growth model and use a stochastic version of a dynamic programming method with an adaptive grid scheme to compute the above mentioned asset price characteristics of a model with loss aversion in preferences. As our results show using loss aversion we get considerably better results than one usually obtains from pure consumption-based asset pricing models including the habit formation variant. 相似文献
39.
Since 1994, unemployed workers in the Danish labour market have participated in active labour market programmes on a large scale. This paper contributes with an assessment of costs and benefits of these programmes. Long-term treatment effects are estimated on a very detailed administrative dataset by propensity score matching. For the years 1995 – 2005 it is found that private job training programmes have substantial positive employment and earnings effects, but also public job training ends up with positive earnings effects. Classroom training does not significantly improve employment or earnings prospects in the long run. When the cost side is taken into account, private and public job training still come out with surplusses, while classroom training leads to a deficit. 相似文献
40.