首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   3744篇
  免费   145篇
  国内免费   1篇
财政金融   475篇
工业经济   247篇
计划管理   595篇
经济学   880篇
综合类   23篇
运输经济   44篇
旅游经济   64篇
贸易经济   800篇
农业经济   125篇
经济概况   631篇
邮电经济   6篇
  2023年   39篇
  2022年   24篇
  2021年   50篇
  2020年   90篇
  2019年   133篇
  2018年   166篇
  2017年   199篇
  2016年   191篇
  2015年   96篇
  2014年   131篇
  2013年   402篇
  2012年   182篇
  2011年   196篇
  2010年   126篇
  2009年   148篇
  2008年   125篇
  2007年   112篇
  2006年   97篇
  2005年   139篇
  2004年   127篇
  2003年   94篇
  2002年   59篇
  2001年   51篇
  2000年   48篇
  1999年   51篇
  1998年   38篇
  1997年   34篇
  1996年   34篇
  1995年   30篇
  1994年   30篇
  1993年   23篇
  1992年   21篇
  1991年   23篇
  1990年   23篇
  1989年   22篇
  1988年   21篇
  1987年   22篇
  1986年   18篇
  1985年   23篇
  1984年   16篇
  1983年   10篇
  1982年   17篇
  1981年   18篇
  1980年   20篇
  1979年   14篇
  1978年   12篇
  1975年   10篇
  1969年   11篇
  1965年   9篇
  1942年   10篇
排序方式: 共有3890条查询结果,搜索用时 31 毫秒
61.
This paper decomposes the redistributive effect on annual and lifetime inquality of a range of taxes and transfers in Australia, using a dynamic cohort lifetime simulation model. The redistributive effect is decomposed into vertical, horizontal and reranking effects. Horizontal inequities in the tax and transfer system are found to be negligible. The extent of reranking is greater in the lifetime than in the annual context and is affected by the equivalence scales used to adjust household incomes. If no adjustment is made to household incomes, reranking is about nine per cent of the reduction in lifetime inequality. However, if each child is counted as equivalent to one-third of an adult, reranking is found to be less than one per cent.  相似文献   
62.
63.
We investigate the interplay between environmental policy, incentives to adoptnew technology, and repercussions on R&D. We study a model where a monopolistic upstream firm engages in R&D and sells advanced abatement technology to polluting downstream firms. We consider four different timing and commitment regimes of environmental tax and permit policies: ex post taxation (or issuing permits), interim commitment to a tax rate (a quota of permits) after observing R&D success but before adoption, and finally two types of ex antecommitment before R&D activity, one with a unique tax rate (quota of permits), the other one with a menu of tax rates (permit quotas). We study the second best tax and permit policies and rank these with respect to welfare. In particular, we find that commitment to a menu of tax rate dominates all other policy regimes.  相似文献   
64.
The theory of optimal currency areas stresses that a single currency zone should have symmetry across shocks and structures. What happens if the monetary transmission mechanisms differ so that a common monetary policy has different effects in different places? Using a fully specified econometric model, we find that such asymmetries are likely to destabilise the business cycle and put countries out of phase with each other in a way that cannot be corrected by deficit-constrained national fiscal policies. Market discipline, however, could achieve this. Hence, the question is whether the markets would create sufficient discipline on their own.  相似文献   
65.
The ‘wage space’, which is defined as the sum of price inflation and labour productivity growth, has played a major role as an indicator of allowable wage increases in the post-war wage negotiations in the Netherlands. This paper shows that: (a) wages and the wage space are co-integrated; (b) the deviation between wages and the wage space may act as an error correction term in the wage equation when both variables are identified as I(2); and (c) political consensus and the threat of labour conflicts (rather than actual strike activity) may be identified as the ‘mechanism’ behind this error correction in the wage equation.  相似文献   
66.
It is generally acknowledged that the growth rate of output, the seasonal pattern, and the business cycle are best estimated simultaneously. To achieve this, we develop an unobserved component time series model for seasonally unadjusted US GDP. Our model incorporates a Markov switching regime to produce periods of expansion and recession, both of which are characterized by different underlying growth rates. Although both growth rates are time-varying, they are assumed to be cointegrated. The analysis is Bayesian, which fully accounts for all sources of uncertainty. Comparison with results from a similar model for seasonally adjusted data indicates that the seasonal adjustment of the data significantly alters several aspects of the full model. First Version Received: January 2001/Final Version Received: February 2002 Send offprint requests to: Rob Luginbuhl?Correspondence to: Rob Luginbuhl  相似文献   
67.
This paper analyses the impact of environmental liability regimes on the capital structure of firms. We show that imposing environmental liability only on polluting firms, with limited liability, increases use of bank debt. Extending environmental liability to banks lowers bank borrowing relative to liability only on firms, with an ambiguous effect relative to no liability. Using US industry-level data we estimate a reduced-form model of bank borrowing by firms and show that the introduction of environmental liability only on firms increased bank borrowing by 15–20%, but when liability was extended to banks, borrowing returned to a level slightly higher than with no liability.  相似文献   
68.
In questa nota si estendono alcuni precedenti risultati dovuti a Beccacece-Castagnoli [1]–[2] e Levi [7], sulla dominanza temporale, stocastica e stocastico-temporale tra flussi finanziari, certi o aleatori, nel caso discreto e finito. Largo spazio viene anche dato ad esempi critici e controesempi.
Summary This paper extends previous results by Beccacece-Castagnoli [1]–[2] and Levi [7] on time dominance, stochastic dominance, time-stochastic dominance for discrete, finite, deterministic or stochastic, cashflows. Last sections are devoted to critical examples and counterexamples.


Ricerca parzialmente finanziata dal M.U.R.S.T. e dall'Università Bocconi.  相似文献   
69.
The living company   总被引:7,自引:0,他引:7  
What can explain the longevity gap between a company that survives for centuries--the Swedish company Stora, for example, which is more than 700 years old--and the average corporation, which does not last 20 years? A team at Royal Dutch/Shell Group explored that question. Arie de Geus, a retired Shell executive, writes about the team's findings and describes what he calls living companies-organizations that have beaten the high mortality rate of the average corporation. Many companies die young, de Geus argues, because their policies and practices are based too heavily on the thinking and language of economics. Their managers focus on producing goods and services and forget that the organization is a community of human beings that is in business--any business--to stay alive. In contrast, managers of living companies consider themselves to be stewards of a long-standing enterprise. Their priorities reflect their commitment to the organization's long-term survival in an unpredictable world. Like careful gardeners, they encourage growth and renewal without endangering the plant they are tending. They value profits the same way most people value oxygen: as necessary for life but not the purpose of it. They scuttle assets when necessary to make a dramatic change in the business portfolio. And they constantly search for new ideas. These managers also focus on developing people. They create opportunities for employees to learn from one another. Such organizations are suited for survival in a world in which success depends on the ability to learn, to adapt, and to evolve.  相似文献   
70.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号