全文获取类型
收费全文 | 49878篇 |
免费 | 967篇 |
国内免费 | 1篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 9330篇 |
工业经济 | 3628篇 |
计划管理 | 7964篇 |
经济学 | 11114篇 |
综合类 | 625篇 |
运输经济 | 339篇 |
旅游经济 | 851篇 |
贸易经济 | 7687篇 |
农业经济 | 2413篇 |
经济概况 | 6769篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
邮电经济 | 125篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 288篇 |
2020年 | 492篇 |
2019年 | 739篇 |
2018年 | 983篇 |
2017年 | 975篇 |
2016年 | 972篇 |
2015年 | 631篇 |
2014年 | 1048篇 |
2013年 | 4934篇 |
2012年 | 1410篇 |
2011年 | 1560篇 |
2010年 | 1277篇 |
2009年 | 1476篇 |
2008年 | 1486篇 |
2007年 | 1318篇 |
2006年 | 1203篇 |
2005年 | 1091篇 |
2004年 | 1103篇 |
2003年 | 1038篇 |
2002年 | 1049篇 |
2001年 | 984篇 |
2000年 | 970篇 |
1999年 | 891篇 |
1998年 | 872篇 |
1997年 | 869篇 |
1996年 | 861篇 |
1995年 | 754篇 |
1994年 | 792篇 |
1993年 | 838篇 |
1992年 | 813篇 |
1991年 | 826篇 |
1990年 | 732篇 |
1989年 | 633篇 |
1988年 | 629篇 |
1987年 | 625篇 |
1986年 | 648篇 |
1985年 | 960篇 |
1984年 | 905篇 |
1983年 | 875篇 |
1982年 | 816篇 |
1981年 | 731篇 |
1980年 | 777篇 |
1979年 | 718篇 |
1978年 | 604篇 |
1977年 | 563篇 |
1976年 | 436篇 |
1975年 | 464篇 |
1974年 | 411篇 |
1973年 | 387篇 |
1972年 | 292篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
11.
Andrew J. Seltzer 《Accounting, Business & Financial History》2004,14(3):237-256
This paper uses evidence from late nineteenth-and early twentieth-century personnel records of two Australian banks to examine the nature of internal labour markets prior to the Second World War. It is argued that the industry possessed all the classic features of internal labour markets: limited ports of entry, internal promotion, long careers, and assignment of wages by well-defined rules. The paper then examines the reasons why banks adopted internal labour markets. Finally, the paper examines the recent decline of internal labour markets and examines the role of technological and social changes in this decline. 相似文献
12.
Poverty Traps and Index-Based Risk Transfer Products 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
13.
Using a sample of Australian Multi-sector trusts we examine selectivity and market timing performance and extend the analysis to include the relatively new measure of volatility timing. This is of particular relevance to our data set, as high levels of volatility persistence are prevalent in Australia. In addition we consider the stability, asymmetry and seasonality of the various performance and risk measures. A survivorship adjustment procedure is also employed in order to assess the impact of survivorship on selectivity, market timing and volatility timing performance. 相似文献
14.
Castaneda Marco A.; Garen John; Thornton Jeremy 《Jnl. of Law, Economics, and Organization》2008,24(1):215-246
This article investigates theoretically and empirically theeffects of competition for donors on the behavior of nonprofitorganizations. Theoretically, we consider a situation in whichnonprofit organizations use donations to produce some commodity,but the use of donations is only partially contractible. Themain results of the model indicate that an increase in competition(i) decreases the fraction of donations allocated to perquisiteconsumption and (ii) increases the fraction of donations allocatedto promotional expenditures. Moreover, the effects of competitionare magnified by the ability to contract on the use of donations.These hypotheses are tested with data on the expenditures ofnonprofit organizations in a number of subsectors where competitionis primarily local. We use across–metropolitan statisticalareas' variation to measure differences in competition and proxycontractibility by the importance of tangible assets, whichare more easily observed by donors. The estimated effects ofcompetition and contractibility are consistent with our model. 相似文献
15.
A. S. Nekrasov S. A. Voronina V. V. Semikashev 《Studies on Russian Economic Development》2008,19(2):136-144
The current progress of electrification in Russia is clearly insufficient compared with G8 countries. At the same time, economy sectors have a high potential for energy saving. The electricity consumption of households depends on their cash income and the growth rate of electricity tariffs. 相似文献
16.
This paper develops and estimates models of family and sex-specific emigration, as well as the sex composition of this emigration, from 12 European source countries to the U.S. for the period 1870–1910. The models are based on the distinction between economic migrants (males, single females, and some married females) and tied or trailing migrants (females) and are estimated with panel data, including data that relate to the occupational/industrial structure of male and female economic activity in source countries. Hausman-Taylor instrumental variable estimates suggest that although both males and females responded to labor-market signals, males were more responsive than females to per capita GDP differences. Moreover, compared to the rest of Europe, Ireland, and Scandinavia were the sources of many young, single male, and female migrants, who responded strongly to gaps in economic opportunities. In fact, much of the European response to such gaps appears to be due to migrants from Ireland and Scandinavia. Females tended to originate in English-speaking countries and countries that were agriculturally oriented. Service and manufacturing jobs in source countries discouraged the migration of females relative to males. Males tended to follow recent migrants more than females, but females responded more to long-term influences as measured by stocks of migrants from their source countries who had previously settled in the U.S. Countries with high birth rates had relatively fewer female emigrants, whereas those with high rates of natural increase 20 years earlier experienced relatively more male emigration. Intact families, other family members (including family-strategy male migrants and trailing female migrants), and single males and females responded strongly to economic incentives, but the singles were most responsive followed by family-strategy males. 相似文献
17.
18.
E. A. Abramova D. R. Belousov K. V. Mikhailenko 《Studies on Russian Economic Development》2008,19(1):35-45
This article examines the economic outcome of 2006 and builds a forecast for 2007–2010. The medium-term development risks of the Russian economy are analyzed. 相似文献
19.
In the presence of foreign factor ownership tariffs change not only the terms of (goods) trade but also income flows between countries. Assume that only the home country owns factors abroad. Then the optimal tariff is negative if and only if foreign factor ownership entails trade-pattern reversals. Trade-pattern reversals are neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition for a negative optimal tariff if the foreign country owns factors in the home country. Changes in the home country's tariff shift the foreign country's offer curve. This adds a new dimension to optimal tariff analysis. 相似文献
20.