首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   1042篇
  免费   47篇
财政金融   223篇
工业经济   119篇
计划管理   174篇
经济学   243篇
综合类   7篇
运输经济   10篇
旅游经济   6篇
贸易经济   224篇
农业经济   23篇
经济概况   60篇
  2024年   1篇
  2023年   10篇
  2022年   4篇
  2021年   15篇
  2020年   19篇
  2019年   39篇
  2018年   36篇
  2017年   38篇
  2016年   45篇
  2015年   25篇
  2014年   46篇
  2013年   151篇
  2012年   49篇
  2011年   61篇
  2010年   52篇
  2009年   54篇
  2008年   32篇
  2007年   46篇
  2006年   32篇
  2005年   37篇
  2004年   32篇
  2003年   31篇
  2002年   36篇
  2001年   25篇
  2000年   14篇
  1999年   12篇
  1998年   16篇
  1997年   16篇
  1996年   13篇
  1995年   13篇
  1994年   14篇
  1993年   14篇
  1992年   5篇
  1991年   3篇
  1989年   4篇
  1988年   3篇
  1987年   2篇
  1986年   5篇
  1985年   7篇
  1984年   4篇
  1983年   4篇
  1982年   2篇
  1981年   4篇
  1980年   3篇
  1979年   4篇
  1978年   3篇
  1977年   3篇
  1976年   2篇
  1974年   2篇
  1968年   1篇
排序方式: 共有1089条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
991.
We use U.S. export and import price indexes to construct a relative purchasing power parity-based model of the nominal U.S. Dollar Index. The model is successful in predicting the future direction of change in the U.S. Dollar Index over a six-month period up to 68% of the time. Finally, the model, in combination with a simple linear, recursive technique, is able to statistically significantly outperform the random walk in predicting the value of the U.S. Dollar Index at terms of less than four months for the period from 1996 to 2005. The paper provides important implications for investors who are interested in the direction of change in the Dollar’s value, forecasting the level of the U.S. Dollar Index, as well as the extent of over- and undervaluation of the U.S. Dollar, in general.  相似文献   
992.
993.
Summary If firms meet in a number of markets, they may respond to an action in one market by reacting in another market. Fear for such retaliation may induce multimarket firms to collude across markets. The paper assesses available theoretical and empirical evidence on the multimarket collusion theory. Moreover, the paper suggests that the theory can be fruitfully applied in the context of European integration. The focus is on collusion by firms which meet in product markets as well as in joint R&D projects. A model develops three propositions, which shed light on the subsequently provided (tentative) evidence on multidimensional contact in an integrating Europe. The discussion may serve as a framework for future research into both the theoretical and the empirical domain with applications to the issue of European integration.We gratefully acknowledge John Hagedoorn for providing access to the MERIT/CATI database, and two referees for their comments. Of course, the usual disclaimer applies  相似文献   
994.
International Advances in Economic Research - This paper discusses a reason for volatility in oil prices. The Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries’ (OPEC’s) revenues are...  相似文献   
995.
Competitive effects of trade: theory and measurement   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
In this paper, I develop a simple model of heterogeneous exporters to a single destination. This model highlights how the response of producer markups to market-level changes in that destination are intrinsically tied to the induced reallocation of export sales to that destination. I discuss how additional assumptions on the shape of demand (originally advocated by Alfred Marshall as his second law of demand) generate specific predictions for the response of those markups and induced product reallocations to increases in market size and competition in a destination: markups fall and market shares are reallocated towards better performing products. Recent evidence on French multi-product exporters strongly confirms this prediction for market share reallocations. The predictions for the markup responses are also consistent with the findings of the large empirical literature on pricing to market and incomplete pass-through.  相似文献   
996.
In an insurance context, the discounted sum of losses within a finite or infinite time period can be described as a randomly weighted sum of a sequence of independent random variables. These independent random variables represent the amounts of losses in successive development years, while the weights represent the stochastic discount factors. In this paper, we investigate the problem of approximating the tail probability of this weighted sum in the case when the losses have Pareto-like distributions and the discount factors are mutually dependent. We also give some simulation results.  相似文献   
997.
Realized variance option and options on quadratic variation normalized to unit expectation are analysed for the property of monotonicity in maturity for call options at a fixed strike. When this condition holds the risk-neutral densities are said to be increasing in the convex order. For Lévy processes, such prices decrease with maturity. A time series analysis of squared log returns on the S&P 500 index also reveals such a decrease. If options are priced to a slightly increasing level of acceptability, then the resulting risk-neutral densities can be increasing in the convex order. Calibrated stochastic volatility models yield possibilities in both directions. Finally, we consider modeling strategies guaranteeing an increase in convex order for the normalized quadratic variation. These strategies model instantaneous variance as a normalized exponential of a Lévy process. Simulation studies suggest that other transformations may also deliver an increase in the convex order.  相似文献   
998.
999.
When a company offers shares in an initial public offering (IPO), existing owners often enter into lock-in agreements prohibiting them from selling shares for a specified period after the IPO. There is some recent US evidence of predictable share-price movements at the time of expiry of these lock-in agreements. Using a sample of 188 firms, 83 classified as high-tech and 105 others, that went public on the London Stock Exchange (LSE) during 1992–1998, we focus on the characteristics of lock-in agreements in the UK and on the behaviour of stocks returns around the lock-in expiry date. We find that the lock-in contracts of LSE-listed firms are much more complex, varied and diverse than US contracts, which usually standardise the lock-in period at 180 days after the IPO. We also find evidence of negative abnormal stock returns at and around lock-in expiry of similar magnitude to those reported in US studies. However, these abnormal returns are typically not statistically significant. While the deterioration in stock returns immediately around the expiry date appears to be particularly much more pronounced for high-tech stocks than for others, the differences in performance are not statistically significant.  相似文献   
1000.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号