首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   163篇
  免费   5篇
财政金融   29篇
工业经济   5篇
计划管理   36篇
经济学   43篇
运输经济   1篇
贸易经济   27篇
农业经济   8篇
经济概况   19篇
  2023年   2篇
  2022年   3篇
  2021年   4篇
  2020年   2篇
  2019年   11篇
  2018年   7篇
  2017年   6篇
  2016年   7篇
  2015年   4篇
  2014年   6篇
  2013年   20篇
  2012年   12篇
  2011年   10篇
  2010年   5篇
  2009年   5篇
  2008年   6篇
  2007年   2篇
  2006年   3篇
  2005年   1篇
  2004年   6篇
  2003年   1篇
  2002年   1篇
  2001年   2篇
  2000年   4篇
  1999年   2篇
  1998年   3篇
  1997年   5篇
  1996年   2篇
  1995年   4篇
  1994年   5篇
  1993年   1篇
  1992年   1篇
  1991年   1篇
  1984年   1篇
  1983年   1篇
  1973年   1篇
  1972年   1篇
  1970年   2篇
  1969年   1篇
  1968年   2篇
  1966年   1篇
  1965年   1篇
  1963年   1篇
  1958年   1篇
  1935年   1篇
排序方式: 共有168条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
111.
Choice Modelling applications can be designed to estimate main effects only or multiple-way interactions between attributes. It has been reported that higher order effects generally account for less than 10% of the choice explanation. Nevertheless, the amount of applications testing for interactions among attributes in environmental valuation is very limited. This paper reports a Choice Modelling exercise valuing climate change impacts on plant cover, land erosion and fire risk in Spanish shrublands. Two out of three two-way interactions were found significant and to account for more than 20% of the choice model explanation. Their contribution to the log-likelihood value was comparable to the one of the main effects variables. Moreover, accounting for second order interactions significantly altered the estimates of the implicit prices of attributes compared to the main effects specifications.  相似文献   
112.
The existing literature on soft budget constraints suggests that firms may be subsidized for political reasons or because of the creditors' desire to recover a part of the sunk cost invested in an earlier period. In all these models hard budget constraints are viewed as being, in principle, capable of inducing the necessary restructuring behaviour on the level of the firm. This paper argues that the imposition of financial discipline is not sufficient to remedy ownership and governance-related deficiencies of corporate performance. Using evidence from the post-communist transition economies, the paper shows that a policy of hard budget constraints cannot induce successful revenue restructuring, which requires entrepreneurial incentives inherent in certain ownership types (most notably, outside investors). The paper also shows that the policy of hard budget constraints falters when state firms, because of inferior revenue performance and less willingness to meet payment obligations, continue to pose a higher credit risk than privatized firms. The brunt of state firms' lower creditworthiness falls on state creditors. But the 'softness' of these creditors, while harmful in many ways, is not necessarily irrational, if it prevents the demise of firms that are in principle capable of successful restructuring through ownership changes.  相似文献   
113.
This paper develops an empirical model to identify the structural parameters of schooling preferences and human capital production. Our model distinguishes between consumption and investment motives with regard to schooling. The results show that both motives matter. Preferences for schooling vary with social background and ability. Children from poorer social backgrounds and of lower ability have a lower preference for schooling. The discount rate that enters the net value of lifetime income varies with social background as well. The marginal rate of return to schooling decreases with ability and schooling. On average the marginal rate of return is 7.3 per cent, which can be contrasted with a `Mincerian' rate of return equal to 4.8 per cent. This indicates that the usual OLS estimate underestimates the true rate of return. First version received: November 1997/Final version received: February 1999  相似文献   
114.
RESUME ** :  Parmi les facteurs contingents du taux de remboursement des microcrédits, la responsabilité solidaire des emprunteurs est peu analysée dans les études empiriques. Grâce à la constitution d'une base de données originale, cet article s'attache à estimer l'impact des facteurs contingents du taux de remboursement, dont la forme du prêt. Les résultats dégagés font apparaître que, d'une part, dans la catégorie des prêts remboursés dans les délais, les prêts individuels offrent un meilleur taux de recouvrement mais aussi, d'autre part, que cet effet s'estompe dès lors que sont incorporés les remboursements tardifs. Parmi les autres facteurs contingents du taux de remboursement, on dénombre principalement la distance entre le lieu de résidence des clients et le siège de l'institution et l'objet du crédit.  相似文献   
115.
116.
117.
118.
Boekbesprekingen     
Hartog  F.  van Rhijn  A. A.  Berg  E. L.  Hessel  W.  Gratama  J. A. Freseman  Greidanus  G.  Barten  A. P.  Lamers  E. A. A. M.  Posthumus  G. A.  v. d. Woestijne  W. J.  Klein  P. W. 《De Economist》1966,114(7-8):440-460
  相似文献   
119.
The time evolution of a sliding bond is studied in discrete‐ and continuous‐time setups. By definition, a sliding bond represents the price process of a discount bond with a fixed time to maturity. Examples of measure‐valued trading strategies (introduced by Bj"ork et al. 1997a, 1997b) which are based on the price process of a sliding bond are discussed. In particular, a self‐financing strategy that involves holding at any time one unit of a sliding bond is examined (the wealth process of this strategy is referred to as the rolling‐horizon bond). In contrast to the sliding bond, which does not represent a tradable security, the rolling‐horizon bond (or the rolling‐consol bond) may play the role of a fixed‐income security with infinite lifespan in portfolio management problems.  相似文献   
120.
This paper compares impulse responses to monetary policy shocks in the euro area countries before the EMU and in the New Member States (NMS) from central–eastern Europe. We mitigate the small‐sample problem, which is especially acute for the NMS, by using a Bayesian estimation that combines information across countries. The impulse responses in the NMS are broadly similar to those in the euro area countries. There is some evidence that in the NMS, which have had higher and more volatile inflation, the Phillips curve is steeper than in the euro area countries. This finding is consistent with economic theory. Copyright © 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号