全文获取类型
收费全文 | 17163篇 |
免费 | 24篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2724篇 |
工业经济 | 787篇 |
计划管理 | 2639篇 |
经济学 | 3956篇 |
综合类 | 488篇 |
运输经济 | 9篇 |
旅游经济 | 4篇 |
贸易经济 | 4575篇 |
农业经济 | 12篇 |
经济概况 | 1376篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 573篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 11篇 |
2022年 | 1篇 |
2021年 | 3篇 |
2020年 | 14篇 |
2019年 | 16篇 |
2018年 | 2316篇 |
2017年 | 2064篇 |
2016年 | 1218篇 |
2015年 | 104篇 |
2014年 | 102篇 |
2013年 | 117篇 |
2012年 | 462篇 |
2011年 | 1961篇 |
2010年 | 1841篇 |
2009年 | 1537篇 |
2008年 | 1526篇 |
2007年 | 1877篇 |
2006年 | 74篇 |
2005年 | 402篇 |
2004年 | 471篇 |
2003年 | 570篇 |
2002年 | 259篇 |
2001年 | 75篇 |
2000年 | 51篇 |
1999年 | 5篇 |
1998年 | 25篇 |
1997年 | 8篇 |
1996年 | 18篇 |
1995年 | 4篇 |
1994年 | 4篇 |
1993年 | 5篇 |
1992年 | 2篇 |
1991年 | 2篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1988年 | 4篇 |
1987年 | 1篇 |
1986年 | 16篇 |
1984年 | 2篇 |
1983年 | 4篇 |
1981年 | 3篇 |
1980年 | 1篇 |
1979年 | 1篇 |
1978年 | 2篇 |
1977年 | 1篇 |
1975年 | 2篇 |
1973年 | 1篇 |
1971年 | 1篇 |
1937年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 14 毫秒
81.
In this paper we test the well-known hypothesis of Obstfeld and Rogoff (NBER Macroeconomics Annual 7777:339–390, 2000) that trade costs are the key to explaining the so-called Feldstein–Horioka puzzle. Our approach has a number of novel features.
First, we focus on the interrelationship between trade costs, the trade account and the Feldstein–Horioka puzzle. Second,
we use the gravity model to estimate the effect of trade costs on bilateral trade and, third, we show how bilateral trade
can be used to draw inferences about desired trade balances and desired intertemporal trade. Our econometric results provide
strong support for the Obstfeld and Rogoff hypothesis and we are also able to reconcile our results with the so-called home
bias puzzle.
相似文献
Jacques Melitz (Corresponding author)Email: |
82.
This paper analyses both quarterly data from the Confederation of British Industry (CBI) Survey on respondents’ expectations
of recent and forthcoming manufacturing output and monthly Office of National Statistics (ONS) figures on actual manufacturing
output within the UK. Quarterly output expectations of the CBI manufacturers are explained from the monthly ONS observations
using a bounded rationality approach. The logistic formulation models the diffusion process across respondents. There is a
backward-looking CBI Survey perspective, explained by past ONS observations, and a forward-looking perspective, explained
from future ONS statistics. Also, the forecasting of monthly manufacturing output from earlier values, along with the quarterly
CBI Survey information, is examined and tested against the alternative Pesaran/Thomas method. The study provides econometric
evidence for the validity of the logistic model and shows that bounded rationality can explain the formation of predictions
among business managers in the UK manufacturing sector. The emerging consensus from the literature, supported by this paper,
is that the logistic format is a superior approximation to the true data generating process compared with the earlier standard
Anderson/Pesaran/Thomas approach. An adjustment to the Survey is used, which achieves perfect symmetry with up and down versions
of the data. The benefits of this adjustment are tested in the forecasting section.
相似文献
David BywatersEmail: |
83.
Nejat Anbarci 《Atlantic Economic Journal》2008,36(3):293-299
It is a well-known fact that several prominent bargaining solutions are responsive to changes in status-quo (i.e., disagreement
or fallback) payoffs. When an agent’s status-quo payoff increases, his solution payoff either stays the same or increases.
A fully general result for these solutions’ status-quo point ranking is impossible to establish. In this paper, using an important
class of bargaining problems, a ranking of the relative status-quo point responsiveness of prominent bargaining solutions
is obtained. Using the Constant Elasticity of Substitution class of bargaining problems, regardless of the concavity of the
Pareto frontier and the level of increase in one’s status-quo payoff, we find the equal gains solution is the most responsive
with respect to changes in status-quo payoffs, followed by the Nash solution. The equal sacrifice solutions is the least responsive,
followed by the Kalai/Smorodinsky solution.
相似文献
Nejat AnbarciEmail: |
84.
85.
Mathias Hoffmann 《Open Economies Review》2008,19(2):183-201
The bulk of evidence on the lack of international risk sharing is based on regressions of idiosyncratic consumption growth
on idiosyncratic output growth. This paper argues that the results from such regressions obtained from international data
are, however, not directly comparable to those based on regional data: the standard practice of running such regressions on
international data fails to account for persistent international differentials in consumer prices, whereas—implicitly—most
of the literature based on regional data has accounted for these differences. When risk sharing regressions are set up in
conceptually the same way in international and regional data sets, the estimated coefficients are also very similar. To explore
this result further, we adapt the variance decomposition of Asdrubali et al. (Q J Econ 111:1081–1110, 1996) to allow for deviations from purchasing power parity across countries. While quantity (income and credit) flows are the
dominant channel of risk sharing among regions, relative consumption and output price (internal terms of trade) fluctuations
account for the bulk of the deviation from the complete markets outcome in international data. To the extent that persistent
differences in consumer prices are an indication of goods market segmentation, our findings provide empirical evidence for
the proposition by Obstfeld and Rogoff (NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, 2000) that segmented international goods markets rather than asset market incompleteness may account for the (apparent) lack of
risk sharing between countries.
相似文献
Mathias HoffmannEmail: URL: www.iew.uzh.ch/itf |
86.
Eric Toulemonde 《Open Economies Review》2008,19(2):203-219
The paper builds an analytically tractable model that illustrates the “proximity–concentration trade-off” involved in horizontal
multinationals. For low trade costs, firms are single-plant firms, for intermediate costs, some are single-plant firms whereas
others are multinationals, for large trade costs, firms are multinationals. Because of the modeling strategy, the model is
suited for a welfare analysis of multinationals. It shows that too many firms choose to concentrate their production in only
one location. Also, for some transport costs, a reduction in transport costs worsens welfare.
相似文献
Eric ToulemondeEmail: |
87.
Ali A Alalwan Yogesh K Dwivedi Nripendra P Rana Banita Lal Michael D Williams 《Journal of Financial Services Marketing》2015,20(2):145-157
Despite the rapid growth of Internet banking (IB), customers in developing countries still hesitate to adopt this technology and its use in the Middle East remains low. This study aims to identify and examine the factors that predict behavioural intention and adoption of IB in Jordan. Four factors – hedonic motivation, habit, self-efficacy and trust – are proposed in a conceptual model. Data was collected by means of a survey with bank customers in Jordan. Structural equation modelling (SEM) was used to analyse the data. The results strongly supported the conceptual model. Further, hedonic motivation, habit, self-efficacy and trust were all confirmed to have a significant influence on behavioural intention. Trust was found to be strongly predicted by both hedonic motivation and self-efficacy. This study provides both academics and practitioners with an insight into the factors that can be used to encourage customer adoption of IB specifically in a Middle East context. 相似文献
88.
This paper applies Plato’s cave allegory to Enron’s success and downfall. Plato’s famous tale of cave dwellers illustrates
the different levels of truth and understanding. These levels include images, the sources of images, and the ultimate reality
behind both. The paper first describes these levels of perception as they apply to Plato’s cave dwellers and then provides
a brief history of the rise of Enron. Then we apply Plato’s levels of understanding to Enron, showing how the company created
its image and presented information to support that image, and how the public eventually emerged from the cave to realize
the truth about Enron’s actual accounting practices and financial state, which led to the corporation’s downfall. We find
Plato’s allegory both useful in analyzing the relationship between Enron and the public and instructive about the power and
moral responsibility of Enron’s executives. 相似文献
89.
Herausforderndes Verhalten bei Demenz - Wenn Aggression, erh?hter Bewegungsdrang, starke Orientierungsprobleme, Selbst- und
Fremdgef?hrdung oder andere „herausfordernde“ Verhaltensweisen auftreten, wird die Pflege und Begleitung von Demenzkranken
als Belastung erlebt. Doch Pflegende stehen dem Problem nicht hilflos gegenüber. Eine interdisziplin?re Expertengruppe gibt
mit ihren Empfehlungen ein Handlungsgerüst. 相似文献
90.
The contextual nature of the predictive power of statistically-based quarterly earnings models 总被引:2,自引:2,他引:0
We present new empirical evidence on the contextual nature of the predictive power of five statistically-based quarterly earnings
expectation models evaluated on a holdout period spanning the twelve quarters from 2000–2002. In marked contrast to extant
time-series work, the random walk with drift (RWD) model provides significantly more accurate pooled, one-step-ahead quarterly
earnings predictions for a sample of high-technology firms (n = 202). In similar predictive comparisons, the Griffin-Watts (GW) ARIMA model provides significantly more accurate quarterly
earnings predictions for a sample of regulated firms (n = 218). Finally, the RWD and GW ARIMA models jointly dominate the other expectation models (i.e., seasonal random walk with
drift, the Brown-Rozeff (BR) and Foster (F) ARIMA models) for a default sample of firms (n = 796). We provide supplementary analyses that document the: (1) increased frequency of the number of loss quarters experienced
by our sample firms in the holdout period (2000–2002) vis-à-vis the identification period (1990–1999); (2) reduced levels
of earnings persistence for our sample firms relative to earnings persistence factors computed by Baginski et al. (2003) during earlier time periods (1970s–1980s); (3) relative impact on the predictive ability of the five expectation models
conditioned upon the extent of analyst coverage of sample firms (i.e., no coverage, moderate coverage, and extensive coverage);
and (4) sensitivity of predictive performance across subsets of regulated firms with the BR ARIMA model providing the most
accurate predictions for utilities (n = 87) while the RWD model is superior for financial institutions (n = 131).
相似文献
Kenneth S. Lorek (Corresponding author)Email: |
G. Lee WillingerEmail: |