首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   69篇
  免费   5篇
财政金融   10篇
工业经济   3篇
计划管理   14篇
经济学   33篇
贸易经济   6篇
经济概况   8篇
  2021年   1篇
  2020年   1篇
  2017年   2篇
  2016年   2篇
  2015年   2篇
  2013年   6篇
  2012年   6篇
  2011年   3篇
  2010年   4篇
  2009年   2篇
  2008年   3篇
  2007年   2篇
  2006年   1篇
  2005年   2篇
  2004年   2篇
  2003年   2篇
  2002年   2篇
  2001年   7篇
  2000年   3篇
  1999年   2篇
  1998年   2篇
  1997年   5篇
  1996年   2篇
  1992年   1篇
  1990年   1篇
  1989年   1篇
  1985年   1篇
  1984年   1篇
  1983年   2篇
  1978年   2篇
  1976年   1篇
排序方式: 共有74条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
51.
This paper empirically analyzes inertia in the position of the dollar as the key currency. We extend a money-in-the-utility model to one with parallel international currencies. We use an extended model to estimate a parameter in the utility function. Also, given the estimated parameter, we simulate a relation between depreciation and share of the dollar. The result indicates that the share of the dollar will not decrease even if the dollar depreciates at a moderate rate. Thus the dollar will keep its position as the key currency – inertia works in the key currency.  相似文献   
52.
RJVs in product innovation and cartel stability   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
Abstract. We characterise the interplay between firms' decision in product development undertaken through a research joint venture (RJV), and the nature of their ensuing market behaviour. Participant firms in an RJV face a trade-off between saving the costs of product innovation by developing similar products to one another, e.g., by sharing most of the basic components of their products, and investing higher initial efforts in product innovation in order to develop more distinct products. We prove that the more the firms' products are distinct and thus less substitutable, the easier their collusion is to sustain in the marketing supergame, either in prices (Bertrand) or in quantities (Cournot). This gives rise to a non-monotone dependence of firms' product portfolio upon their intertemporal preferences. Received: 1 October 1998 / Accepted: 14 December 2002 We thank the seminar audience at Centre for Industrial Economics, University of Copenhagen, where all three authors were affiliated at the time we presented the first draft of this paper, and also the two anonymous referees for Review of Economic Design for their detailed comments. The usual disclaimer applies.  相似文献   
53.
For some time, two major kinds of Total Factor Productivity (TFP) have existed independently of each other: the Solow residual and the Malmquist Productivity Index (MPI). The Solow residual was introduced in macro economic growth models, and the MPI has been used in micro economics and management studies. As both indices were developed independently, few studies utilize both together and compare the results. This paper uses the same data to compare the two productivity indices by setting to determine the economic implications of combining the two indices. We discovered that we could decompose TFP with each aspect of the Soiow residual and MPI. We could then interpret their relationship in the business cycle. Our results indicated that the frontier shift in MPI of Japanese firms often occurred when the Solow residual increased, meaning that improving oroductivitv with the Solow residual could be generated by a firm that could shift new production frontiers.  相似文献   
54.
55.
56.
In contrast to traditional assumptions about Asian conflict management, interdependence may induce cooperative approaches to conflict rather than avoidance or competition. Findings from supervisors on 216 subcontractors in Korea, Japan, and Hong Kong support the hypotheses that interdependence leads to cooperative conflict which results in constructive conflict which in turn helps the subcontractor contribute to the main contractor. However, competitive and avoiding conflict were found to be useful in Taiwan. Results were interpreted as suggesting that the theory of cooperation and competition offers the potential for strengthening conflict management in East Asia and that cooperative conflict, rather than avoiding, may reinforce feelings of interdependence in East Asia.  相似文献   
57.
58.
We calculate partial factor productivity and total factor productivity (TFP) indices for rice production using panel data across 42 Japanese prefectures from 1996 to 2006, and perform panel unit root tests of TFP convergence across prefectures. We find that during this period, the partial factor productivity growth rates for capital, land and materials stagnated at the aggregate national level, as did the TFP growth rate, despite a large increase in labor productivity. We also identify evidence of a convergence in TFP across Japanese prefectures.  相似文献   
59.
60.
Service marketing, total quality management, and human resource management researchers have proposed that employee teamwork is a foundation for service quality. North American research suggests that developing cooperative relationships and constructive controversy among employees can empower employees to serve customers and to strengthen their work relationships and commitment to the organization. Chinese employees in an American-style restaurant in Hong Kong were interviewed on specific incidents that affected service quality. Correlational and structural equation results support the hypotheses that cooperative goals help employees discuss their diverse views open-mindedly and that this constructive controversy results in quality customer service. Competitive and independent goals were largely negatively correlated with dynamics and outcomes. Results were interpreted as suggesting that service teams should develop strong cooperative goals and the skills and procedures of constructive controversy. Deutsch's theory of cooperation and competition, although developed largely through North American research, seems useful for understanding and developing service quality teamwork in Asia.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号