全文获取类型
收费全文 | 15472篇 |
免费 | 357篇 |
国内免费 | 13篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 3107篇 |
工业经济 | 1139篇 |
计划管理 | 2580篇 |
经济学 | 3252篇 |
综合类 | 344篇 |
运输经济 | 126篇 |
旅游经济 | 235篇 |
贸易经济 | 2406篇 |
农业经济 | 690篇 |
经济概况 | 1949篇 |
信息产业经济 | 2篇 |
邮电经济 | 12篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 78篇 |
2021年 | 164篇 |
2020年 | 238篇 |
2019年 | 272篇 |
2018年 | 369篇 |
2017年 | 391篇 |
2016年 | 336篇 |
2015年 | 244篇 |
2014年 | 405篇 |
2013年 | 1680篇 |
2012年 | 473篇 |
2011年 | 588篇 |
2010年 | 583篇 |
2009年 | 531篇 |
2008年 | 503篇 |
2007年 | 431篇 |
2006年 | 413篇 |
2005年 | 323篇 |
2004年 | 296篇 |
2003年 | 300篇 |
2002年 | 287篇 |
2001年 | 287篇 |
2000年 | 296篇 |
1999年 | 294篇 |
1998年 | 301篇 |
1997年 | 264篇 |
1996年 | 223篇 |
1995年 | 219篇 |
1994年 | 235篇 |
1993年 | 240篇 |
1992年 | 263篇 |
1991年 | 252篇 |
1990年 | 201篇 |
1989年 | 182篇 |
1988年 | 166篇 |
1987年 | 163篇 |
1986年 | 167篇 |
1985年 | 238篇 |
1984年 | 255篇 |
1983年 | 244篇 |
1982年 | 211篇 |
1981年 | 194篇 |
1980年 | 168篇 |
1979年 | 167篇 |
1978年 | 156篇 |
1977年 | 133篇 |
1976年 | 123篇 |
1975年 | 139篇 |
1974年 | 99篇 |
1973年 | 100篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
81.
As part of an investigation into the performance of heating systems and the effectiveness of energy saving measures, temperatures have been monitored in forty centrally heated homes. The addition of extra insulation had no effect on the way people operated their heating system or on the temperature level set in the main living room. However, bedrooms were warmer and the importance of individual room temperature controls demonstrated. Differences between people's thermal requirements in domestic and office environments are considered. 相似文献
82.
83.
J. S. Nix 《Journal of Agricultural Economics》1990,41(3):265-291
The paper begins by recording Journal articles since 1952 of relevance to farming incomes and efficiency, and follows by reviewing the literature on measuring farmers' incomes and the problems entailed, including consideration of non-farming incomes and capital gains and their relevance to agricultural policy. Definitions of ‘profit’ in selected economic texts are then compared, together with attempts to measure ‘pure profit’ from farming. Suitable charges for management and interest are then determined and estimates made of net profits and losses from different types of farming in 1986/7 and 1987/8 for both average and ‘top’ farms. Real farming incomes and capital gains from land from 1938 to 1988 are then discussed. The paper concludes by summarising why the concept of profitability from farming has now largely lost its significance—though not for all farmers. 相似文献
84.
This article examines whether ties to portfolio firms’ management via pension business relationships provide mutual funds with an informational advantage. Funds become related to portfolio companies when fund families serve as trustees for firms’ employee pension plans. Selling by related funds is more likely to be motivated by an information advantage than their buying, because the latter is heavily influenced by the desire to secure pension inflows. We find that stocks with larger net sales by related funds experience lower future returns. Information appears related to firm fundamentals, as the return predictability of related funds’ selling concentrates in stocks with negative future earnings surprises. Consistent with an information‐based explanation, the predictive power of related funds’ selling for future returns is more pronounced when information uncertainty about the stock is higher. Our results contribute to a growing literature that shows the sources of informed trading by institutions. 相似文献
85.
Eric S. Rosengren 《Atlantic Economic Journal》2018,46(2):139-150
The current monetary policy debate has focused on current estimates and the future path of the natural rate of unemployment and the equilibrium interest rate. Estimates of the natural rate of unemployment should vary over time with changes in demographics and improvements in human capital. However, these changes should be gradual. This paper shows that the estimates of the natural rate of unemployment by Federal Reserve officials and private-sector economists seem to move pro-cyclically, potentially showing too much weight given to short-term fluctuations in economic variables. As with the natural rate, there are good reasons to expect the equilibrium interest rate to change over time. In fact, the level may actually be more responsive to current economic data, reflecting changes in aggregate savings and investment. Yet, we see that equilibrium interest rate estimates by both Federal Reserve officials and private-sector economists have declined quite dramatically over the past five years. A potential concern raised in this paper is that estimates of these critical economic variables for policy determination appear to be overly sensitive to high frequency economic data. 相似文献
86.
87.
88.
区域经济协调发展与财税政策研究 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
张楠 《山西财政税务专科学校学报》2012,14(5):34-36
区域发展不平衡是当前我国经济发展中遇到的最大问题,这与财税政策有着密切的关系。本文分析了我国财税政策在协调区域经济发展方面存在的问题,提出了规范转移支付制度、调整中央和地方共享税范围与比例、适时开征财产税以及改变现行税收优惠措施等一系列政策建议,以期为促进我国区域经济协调发展有所裨益。 相似文献
89.
Rashpal S. Ahluwalia 《工程经济学家》2013,58(2):197-199
In a recent paper, Jones and Zydiak [2] discuss the steady state fleet design problem, which has no natural initial distribution of vehicles. For this problem, they develop a new optimality criterion of minimizing annual equivalent cost per vehicle because the traditional optimally criterion of minimizing annual equivalent cost can lead to paradoxical results, as shown by example, when applied to the fleet design problem. In a subsequent note, Hartman [1] argues that this paradox is actually a result of a replacement convention that ignores opportunity costs. In this response, we demonstrate that paradoxical replacement behavior can occur with the traditional criterion even when opportunity costs are accounted for in the replacement analysis. We further conclude that the problems considered respectively by Jones and Zydiak [2] and Hartman [1] are fundamentally different in nature. 相似文献
90.
Information technology has always played an important role in the services sector of the U.S. economy. In recent years, however, services industries have stepped up their acquisitions of computers, telecommunications equipment, and other such products dramatically. As a result, the broad segment of the economy that can be classified as services providers now owns about 84% of the total U.S. stock of information technology items. Moreover, relative to goods-producing industries, a much larger proportion of the services sector's capital budgets is spent on information technology, revealing a significantly greater dependence by services on such technology as a factor of production. This reliance underscores technology's strategic importance in the United States' competitive challenge. With services now the predominant mode of economic activity in the United States, a productivity payback from information technology is absolutely essential to keep the economy on a longer term path of sustainable growth.So far, the services sector has little to show for its spending binge on technology. Quite simply, massive investments in information technology have failed to boost national productivity growth in the present decade. Furthermore, with manufacturing productivity now on the rebound, problems in the services sector loom increasingly large in the United States' broader competitive struggle. It is certainly not too late. New and creative applications of information technology could still enhance the productivity performance of the services sector's predominantly white-collar work force. Until that payback begins to occur, however, the role of technology spending will be under growing suspicion [3, 8, 9].In what follows, an attempt is made to provide a detailed industry-by-industry assessment of services sector spending on information technology. By way of background, the broad contours of capital formation in services industries are first examined over the post-World War II era. 相似文献