首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   12782篇
  免费   233篇
财政金融   2246篇
工业经济   884篇
计划管理   2100篇
经济学   2779篇
综合类   96篇
运输经济   86篇
旅游经济   180篇
贸易经济   1987篇
农业经济   714篇
经济概况   1901篇
信息产业经济   1篇
邮电经济   41篇
  2020年   118篇
  2019年   199篇
  2018年   281篇
  2017年   261篇
  2016年   269篇
  2015年   165篇
  2014年   280篇
  2013年   1108篇
  2012年   373篇
  2011年   379篇
  2010年   309篇
  2009年   375篇
  2008年   345篇
  2007年   307篇
  2006年   292篇
  2005年   253篇
  2004年   254篇
  2003年   251篇
  2002年   256篇
  2001年   225篇
  2000年   254篇
  1999年   221篇
  1998年   208篇
  1997年   187篇
  1996年   206篇
  1995年   183篇
  1994年   197篇
  1993年   191篇
  1992年   208篇
  1991年   207篇
  1990年   206篇
  1989年   180篇
  1988年   143篇
  1987年   151篇
  1986年   171篇
  1985年   250篇
  1984年   225篇
  1983年   197篇
  1982年   199篇
  1981年   199篇
  1980年   188篇
  1979年   189篇
  1978年   166篇
  1977年   156篇
  1976年   148篇
  1975年   150篇
  1974年   118篇
  1973年   116篇
  1972年   106篇
  1971年   83篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
981.
982.
983.
Introducing a discussion of some of the ways in which accounting and other calculative mechanisms are involved in environmental matters, the article focuses on a number of questions that emerge from accounting for carbon emission permits and corporate environmental reporting. Both are areas where there is already a need for more research and where that need will increase in the coming years. Identifying some of the interests and pressures that already influence approaches in the area, the case is made for the need for both critical and facilitative research.  相似文献   
984.
abstract    Previous research has portrayed buyer–supplier and supplier–supplier alliances as important mechanisms to foster learning and exchange efficiencies. Controversy remains, however, as to how these alliances interact. While some propose they reinforce one another (e.g. learning in horizontal ties generates positive spillovers to vertical ties), others propose a negative interplay (e.g. when increasing vertical-tie intensity, suppliers may weaken horizontal ties to avoid retaliation from buyers who wish to preserve bargaining power). We empirically test these competing views using survey data from the Brazilian auto-parts industry. In an attempt at reconciliation, we propose that the positive or negative interaction between vertical and horizontal alliances depends on the level of technological uncertainty of goods exchanged. Vertical ties seem to inhibit horizontal ties when technological uncertainty is low; when technological uncertainty is higher, vertical and horizontal ties do not seem to have any meaningful form of interaction. We discuss implications for theory and practice.  相似文献   
985.
986.
987.
Executive compensation: a calibration approach   总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2  
Summary. We use a version of the Grossman and Hart principal-agent model with 10 actions and 10 states to produce quantitative predictions for executive compensation. Performance incentives derived from the model are compared with the performance incentives of 350 firms chosen from a survey by Michael Jensen and Kevin Murphy. The results suggest both that the model does a reasonable job of explaining the data and that actual incentives are close to the optimal incentives predicted by theory. Received: August 12, 1997; revised version: October 27, 1997  相似文献   
988.
989.
990.
The Austrian School of economics—the causal-realist, marginalist, subjectivist tradition established by Carl Menger in 1871—has experienced a remarkable renaissance over the last five decades. It is not always clear, however, exactly what distinguishes the Austrian School from other traditions, schools of thought, approaches, or movements within economics and its sister disciplines. This paper argues that Austrian economics, while part of a broader tradition emphasizing the coordination of the market order, is nonetheless a distinct kind of economic analysis, and that its essence is not subjectivism, the market process, or spontaneous order, but what I call “mundane economics”—price theory, capital theory, monetary theory, business-cycle theory, and the theory of interventionism. Call this the “hard core” of Austrian economics. I argue that this hard core is (1) distinct, and not merely a verbal rendition of mid-twentieth-century neoclassical economics; (2) the unique foundation for applied Austrian analysis (political economy, social theory, business administration, and the like); and (3) a living, evolving body of knowledge, rooted in classic contributions of the past but not bound by them. Most Austrian economists from Menger to Rothbard devoted their energies to developing and communicating the principles of mundane economics, not because they failed to grasp the importance of time, uncertainty, knowledge, expectations, institutions, and market processes, but because they regarded these issues as subordinate to the main task of economic science, namely the construction of a more satisfactory theory of value, production, exchange, price, money, capital, and intervention.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号