首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   304篇
  免费   19篇
财政金融   47篇
工业经济   23篇
计划管理   55篇
经济学   87篇
综合类   1篇
运输经济   5篇
旅游经济   10篇
贸易经济   69篇
农业经济   6篇
经济概况   8篇
邮电经济   12篇
  2023年   8篇
  2021年   4篇
  2020年   12篇
  2019年   18篇
  2018年   22篇
  2017年   29篇
  2016年   28篇
  2015年   6篇
  2014年   11篇
  2013年   60篇
  2012年   9篇
  2011年   11篇
  2010年   15篇
  2009年   17篇
  2008年   8篇
  2007年   9篇
  2006年   11篇
  2005年   4篇
  2004年   3篇
  2003年   5篇
  2002年   1篇
  2001年   1篇
  2000年   4篇
  1999年   4篇
  1998年   2篇
  1997年   2篇
  1996年   1篇
  1995年   3篇
  1992年   1篇
  1990年   1篇
  1986年   1篇
  1985年   2篇
  1984年   3篇
  1983年   1篇
  1982年   2篇
  1981年   1篇
  1980年   1篇
  1976年   1篇
  1944年   1篇
排序方式: 共有323条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
321.
Underreporting and undersampling biases in top tail wealth, although widely acknowledged, have not been statistically quantified so far, essentially because they are not readily observable. Here we exploit the functional form of power law-like regimes in top tail wealth to derive analytical expressions for these biases, and use German microdata from a popular survey and rich list to illustrate that tiny differences in non-response rates lead to tail wealth estimates that differ by an order of magnitude, in our case ranging from 1 to 9 trillion euros. Underreporting seriously compounds the problem, and we find that the estimation of totals in scale-free systems oftentimes tends to be spurious. Our findings also suggest that recent debates on the existence of scale- or type-dependence in returns to wealth are ill-posed because the available data cannot discriminate between scale- or type-dependence, on one hand, and statistical biases, on the other hand. Yet both economic theory and mathematical formalism indicate that sampling and reporting biases are more plausible explanations for the observed data than scale- or type-dependence.  相似文献   
322.
We analyze insurance demand when insurable losses come with an uninsurable zero-mean background risk that increases in the loss size. If the individual is risk vulnerable, loss-dependent background risk triggers a precautionary insurance motive and increases optimal insurance demand. Prudence alone is sufficient for insurance demand to increase in two cases: the case of fair insurance and the case where the smallest possible loss exceeds a certain threshold value (referred to as the large loss case). We derive conditions under which insurance demand increases or decreases in initial wealth. In the large loss case, prudence determines whether changes in the background risk lead to more insurance demand. We generalize this result to arbitrary loss distributions and find conditions based on decreasing third-degree Ross risk aversion, Arrow–Pratt risk aversion, and Arrow–Pratt temperance.  相似文献   
323.
Health insurer medical loss ratios (MLRs) are the percentage of premium dollar spent on medical claims and healthcare quality improvement expenses (QIEs). QIEs include activities to improve patient health outcomes and safety, reduce medical errors, and prevent hospital readmissions. The Affordable Care Act mandates minimum MLRs in certain health insurance markets lest rebates be paid to policyholders. QIEs are reported in all markets regardless of whether that market is subject to minimum MLR requirements. Using health insurer statutory filings for a sample of group market insurers from 2010 to 2018, we employ a mixed regression discontinuity/regression kink approach to evaluate whether QIEs are used by insurers as a potential strategy for meeting the minimum MLR requirement. We show that health insurers' QIE increase in the loss ratio until meeting the minimum MLR requirement, have a significant discontinuous jump at the threshold, and decrease above the threshold after the introduction of the MLR mandate.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号