全文获取类型
收费全文 | 17494篇 |
免费 | 38篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2742篇 |
工业经济 | 824篇 |
计划管理 | 2711篇 |
经济学 | 4015篇 |
综合类 | 493篇 |
运输经济 | 20篇 |
旅游经济 | 28篇 |
贸易经济 | 4656篇 |
农业经济 | 32篇 |
经济概况 | 1395篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 572篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 18篇 |
2022年 | 6篇 |
2021年 | 8篇 |
2020年 | 21篇 |
2019年 | 31篇 |
2018年 | 2333篇 |
2017年 | 2090篇 |
2016年 | 1250篇 |
2015年 | 115篇 |
2014年 | 113篇 |
2013年 | 177篇 |
2012年 | 460篇 |
2011年 | 1971篇 |
2010年 | 1841篇 |
2009年 | 1550篇 |
2008年 | 1529篇 |
2007年 | 1887篇 |
2006年 | 80篇 |
2005年 | 402篇 |
2004年 | 476篇 |
2003年 | 561篇 |
2002年 | 267篇 |
2001年 | 80篇 |
2000年 | 57篇 |
1999年 | 15篇 |
1998年 | 24篇 |
1997年 | 7篇 |
1996年 | 20篇 |
1995年 | 10篇 |
1994年 | 6篇 |
1993年 | 10篇 |
1992年 | 9篇 |
1991年 | 7篇 |
1990年 | 9篇 |
1989年 | 9篇 |
1988年 | 5篇 |
1987年 | 5篇 |
1986年 | 21篇 |
1985年 | 5篇 |
1984年 | 3篇 |
1983年 | 3篇 |
1982年 | 4篇 |
1981年 | 9篇 |
1980年 | 3篇 |
1978年 | 5篇 |
1976年 | 2篇 |
1974年 | 2篇 |
1973年 | 3篇 |
1972年 | 3篇 |
1967年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
51.
Mario González María del Mar Alonso-Almeida David Dominguez 《Quality and Quantity》2018,52(3):1041-1055
This study maps the General Reporting Initiative (GRI) relations for a set of global enterprises. Enterprise interrelationships are built using the Mutual Information (MI) of the data reported by enterprises. From the MI topology, we describe interrelationships among the enterprises using chord diagrams to represent the inter- and intra-connectivity between geographical regions and economic sectors globally, by continent and country. Detailed maps are presented for European and Asian regions/sectors, including the relationship between Europe and Asia’s top reporting countries. Our findings reinforce previous research regarding the role of Europe as a driver of sustainability and its influence worldwide. We also determined that Spain is a major player in Europe and that Northern Europe does not have the assumed leading role mentioned in related studies. Eastern Asia is, by far, the leader of the region, and the GRI maps demonstrate the preponderant role of China in the region and the minimal role of India. MI topology maps outline the behavior of the economic sectors, for all the studied regions. Furthermore, a measure that relates the inter- to intra-connections is presented to describe the internal an external relationships among regions/sectors. 相似文献
52.
Brigitte Hoogendoorn Cornelius A. Rietveld André van Stel 《Journal of Evolutionary Economics》2016,26(3):519-550
This cross-country study adopts a competing theories approach in which both a value perspective and a social capital perspective are used to understand the relation between religion and a country’s business ownership rate. We distinguish among four dimensions of religion: belonging to a religious denomination, believing certain religious propositions, bonding to religious practices, and behaving in a religious manner. An empirical analysis of data from 30 OECD countries with multiple data points per country covering the period 1984–2010 suggests a positive relationship between religion and business ownership based on those dimensions that reflect the internal aspects of religiosity (i.e., believing and behaving). We do not observe a significant association for those dimensions that reflect more external aspects of religion (i.e., belonging and bonding). These results suggest that the social capital perspective prevails the value perspective, at least when internal aspects of religiosity are concerned. More generally, our study demonstrates the importance of distinguishing between different dimensions of religion when investigating the link between religion and entrepreneurship. 相似文献
53.
Richard A. Epstein 《Journal of Bioeconomics》2008,10(3):279-285
This article critiques the efforts by Janet Landa, David Sloan Wilson and others to use group selection paradigms to explain
the success of homogenous middlemen groups (HMGs). It argues that group selection theory cannot explain the conflicts of interests
that arise within HMGs or why they dissolve in certain occasions. Landa’s earlier explanations, which stressed the combination
of genetic (kinship) and social bonds in the creation of trust and cooperation in the extension of credit and the creation
of local public goods, better predicts both the strength and weaknesses of HMGs.
相似文献
54.
We estimate the economic value of mortality risk in China using the compensating-wage-differential method. We find a positive
and statistically significant correlation between wages and occupational fatality risk. The estimated effect is largest for
unskilled workers. Unemployment reduces compensation for risk, which suggests that some of the assumptions under which compensating
wage differentials can be interpreted as measures of workers’ preferences for risk and income are invalid when unemployment
is high. Workers may be unwilling to quit high-risk jobs when alternative employment is difficult to obtain, violating the
assumption of perfect mobility, or some workers (e.g., new migrants) may be poorly informed about between-job differences
in risk, violating the assumption of perfect information. These factors suggest our estimates of the value per statistical
life (VSL) in China, which range from approximately US$30,000 to US$100,000, may be biased downward. Alternative estimates
adjust for heterogeneity of risk within industry by assuming that risk is concentrated among low-skill workers. These estimates,
which are likely to be biased downward, range from US$7,000 to US$20,000.
相似文献
55.
Differentiating ambiguity: an expository note 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Ghirardato et al. J Econ Theory 118:133–173, 2004 propose a method for distinguishing between perceived ambiguity and the
decision-maker’s reaction to it. They study a general class of preferences which they refer to as invariant biseparable. This class includes CEU and MEU. This note presents some examples which illustrate their results.
Research supported by ESRC grant no. RES-000-22-0650. For comments and discussion we would like to thank Klaus Nehring and
a seminar audience at ESEM, Vienna 2006. 相似文献
56.
Repeated dichotomous choice contingent valuation data are generated from responses to a succession of binary questions regarding
alternative prices for an environmental good. In this paper we propose a simultaneous equation model that allows for endogeneity
and error correlation across the responses at each stage of the bidding process. The model allows us to study the evolution
of anchoring effects after the second dichotomous choice question. Estimation involves the Bayesian techniques of Gibbs sampling
and data augmentation, and the application focuses on the preservation value of a natural area. The results for a data set
involving up to four successive dichotomous choice questions show that restricted multiple-bounded models are rejected by
the data with the general model. In addition, willingness to pay tends to stabilize after the second stage in the elicitation
process for the general unrestricted model. When taking anchoring effects into consideration, it is revealed that individuals’
responses in the latter stages are influenced by the sequence of bid prices offered in earlier questions. Nevertheless, they
do not have a significant effect on welfare estimates.
相似文献
57.
Aditya Bhattacharjea 《Review of Industrial Organization》2017,51(2):173-191
The starting point of this paper is a January 1977 judgment of the Indian Supreme Court, which applied the rule of reason to vertical restraints and anticipated many of the arguments of the Sylvania judgment. After summarizing the background of the Indian case, I set out the main points of similarity and difference between the two judgments, and finally assess the somewhat erratic influence of post-Sylvania antitrust thinking on Indian competition law and jurisprudence. 相似文献
58.
Carson W. Bays 《International Advances in Economic Research》2007,13(1):81-96
The idea that changes in Supreme Court decision rules should have measurable effects on the volume of cases litigated has
a compelling plausibility, and several models of litigation predict this result. The prediction is a fragile one, however,
because it implies very restrictive assumptions about the probability distributions of the cases subject to dispute. The period
studied includes four Supreme Court decisions widely regarded as changing the rules and altering the level of uncertainty
surrounding the legality of the anti-tying provisions of the antitrust laws. Broad trends in antitrust activity generally
and changes in firm profitability statistically explain over three-quarters of the observed variation in tying litigation.
Changes in legal precedent have only modest effects upon litigation.
相似文献
Carson W. BaysEmail: |
59.
Leland B. Yeager 《The Review of Austrian Economics》2010,23(2):183-191
A prominent philosophical/legal case for requiring 100% bank reserves employs a flawed style of argument. It involves essentialism (criticized by Karl Popper and Joseph Schumpeter), persuasive definitions (identified by Charles L. Stevenson), faulty classification, and the piling up of irrelevant facts and considerations. 相似文献
60.
We consider the game in which b buyers each seek to purchase 1 unit of an indivisible good from s sellers, each of whom has k units to sell. The good is worth 0 to each seller and 1 to each buyer. Using the central limit theorem, and implicitly convergence
to tied down Brownian motion, we find a closed form solution for the limiting Shapley value as s and b increase without bound. This asymptotic value depends upon the seller size k, the limiting ratio b/ks of buyers to items for sale, and the limiting ratio of the excess supply relative to the square root of the number of market participants.
This work was sponsered in part by NSF Grant DMS-03-01795. 相似文献