首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   47篇
  免费   0篇
财政金融   5篇
计划管理   5篇
经济学   36篇
贸易经济   1篇
  2015年   1篇
  2014年   1篇
  2012年   1篇
  2011年   1篇
  2010年   2篇
  2007年   1篇
  2006年   2篇
  2005年   2篇
  2003年   2篇
  2002年   2篇
  2001年   2篇
  1998年   1篇
  1997年   1篇
  1994年   1篇
  1993年   1篇
  1992年   1篇
  1990年   4篇
  1989年   1篇
  1985年   1篇
  1983年   1篇
  1982年   1篇
  1981年   2篇
  1980年   2篇
  1979年   1篇
  1977年   3篇
  1976年   1篇
  1975年   2篇
  1974年   3篇
  1968年   2篇
  1957年   1篇
排序方式: 共有47条查询结果,搜索用时 109 毫秒
31.
We recast the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) in the broader context of general equilibrium with incomplete markets (GEI). In this setting we give proofs of three properties of CAPM equilibria: they are efficient, asset prices lie on a security market line, and all agents hold the same two mutual funds. The first property requires a riskless asset, the latter two do not. We show that across all GEI only one of these three properties of equilibrium is generally valid: asset prices depend on covariances, not variances. We extend CAPM to many consumption goods in such a way that all three properties hold. But now the definition of a riskless asset depends on preferences and endowments, and so cannot be specifieda priori.We wish to acknowledge assistance of NSF Grant No. 88-12051, and a referee's comments. We are grateful for conversations with H. Polemarchakis, especially concerning Section II.4.  相似文献   
32.
Games of Status     
A status game is a cooperative game in which the outcomes are rank orderings of the players. They are a good model for certain situations in which players care about how their "status" compares with that of other players.
We present several formal models within this class. Included are authoritarian status games (where coalitions may assign positions in the rank ordering to nonmembers) and oligarchic status games (where they are unableto do so). We consider the issues of a value concept for authoritarian games and that of core existence for oligarchic games. We then add a transferable resource to the models, obtaining "games of wealth and status."
Finally, we consider an interesting variant, called a "secession game," where coalitions have the right to secede from the grand coalition and form their own smaller "subsocieties," each with its own hierarchy.  相似文献   
33.
The paper investigates the conditions under which an abstractly given market game will have the property that if there is a continuum of traders then every noncooperative equilibrium is Walrasian. In orther words, we look for a general axiomatization of Cournot's well-known result. Besides some convexity, continuity, and nondegeneracy hypotheses, the crucial axioms are: anonymity (i.e., the names of traders are irrelevant to the market) and aggregation (i.e., the net trade received by a trader depends only on his own action and the mean action of all traders). It is also shown that the same axioms do not guarantee efficiency if there is only a finite number of traders. Some examples are discussed and a notion of strict noncooperative equilibrium for anonymous games is introduced.  相似文献   
34.
Dubey  Pradeep  Geanakoplos  John  Shubik  Martin 《Economic Theory》2003,21(4):767-782
Summary. Gold and tobacco have both been used as commodity money. One difference between the two is that gold yields utility, on account of its beauty, without diminishing its quantity. Tobacco yields utility when it is consumed. If this were the only difference, Received: January 2, 2001; revised version: February 22, 2002 Correspondence to: J. Geanakoplos  相似文献   
35.
Summary. We argue that real uncertainty itself causes long-run nominal inflation. Consider an infinite horizon cash-in-advance economy with a representative agent and real uncertainty, modeled by independent, identically distributed endowments. Suppose the central bank fixes the nominal rate of interest. We show that the equilibrium long-run rate of inflation is strictly higher, on almost every path of endowment realizations, than it would be if the endowments were constant.Indeed, we present an explicit formula for the long-run rate of inflation, based on the famous Fisher equation. The Fisher equation says the short-run rate of inflation should equal the nominal rate of interest less the real rate of interest. The long-run Fisher equation for our stochastic economy is similar, but with the rate of inflation replaced by the harmonic mean of the growth rate of money.Received: 25 February 2005, Revised: 26 May 2005, JEL Classification Numbers: C7, C73, D81, E41, E58.An earlier version of this paper “Inflationary Bias in a Simple Stochastic Economy,” as a 2001 Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1333.  相似文献   
36.
37.
38.
39.
40.
This paper is designed to combine the game-theoretic investigation of the static or equilibrium properties of large strategic market games together with the investigation of some very simple dynamics, which nevertheless are sufficient to show differences between two related games, one with only trade and one in which both borrowing from an outside bank and trade take place. The role of banking reserves emerges as relevant and sensitive to the transient state dynamics.Several 100,000 player games are simulated and the behavior is compared with the analytical prediction for the games with a continuum of agents.The dynamics considered here is so simple that it does not show adaptive learning. A natural extension calls for updating via a learning program such as a genetic algorithm.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号