首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   510篇
  免费   26篇
财政金融   70篇
工业经济   44篇
计划管理   104篇
经济学   90篇
综合类   12篇
运输经济   5篇
旅游经济   21篇
贸易经济   152篇
农业经济   20篇
经济概况   18篇
  2023年   16篇
  2022年   4篇
  2021年   7篇
  2020年   15篇
  2019年   23篇
  2018年   27篇
  2017年   34篇
  2016年   31篇
  2015年   16篇
  2014年   18篇
  2013年   70篇
  2012年   20篇
  2011年   21篇
  2010年   8篇
  2009年   24篇
  2008年   17篇
  2007年   18篇
  2006年   6篇
  2005年   13篇
  2004年   10篇
  2003年   5篇
  2002年   11篇
  2001年   13篇
  2000年   8篇
  1999年   7篇
  1998年   6篇
  1997年   5篇
  1996年   4篇
  1995年   6篇
  1994年   2篇
  1993年   8篇
  1992年   4篇
  1991年   5篇
  1990年   5篇
  1989年   5篇
  1988年   2篇
  1987年   3篇
  1986年   8篇
  1985年   4篇
  1984年   2篇
  1981年   2篇
  1978年   5篇
  1975年   1篇
  1974年   1篇
  1973年   3篇
  1972年   3篇
  1971年   1篇
  1970年   1篇
  1968年   1篇
  1967年   2篇
排序方式: 共有536条查询结果,搜索用时 31 毫秒
151.
Developing‐country multinationals (DMNCs) make overseas acquisitions to leverage extant capabilities of acquired companies in order to enter foreign markets and acquire their know‐how to enhance their own competitiveness against global competition at home and abroad. We go “inside the black box” to examine how DMNCs manage those acquisitions and the attendant implications for postacquisition performance. When DMNCs keep the acquired firm “structurally separate” from their own organization and retain its senior executives, they exhibit better acquisition performance. Also, “linking mechanisms” to coordinate interdependencies between the two firms improves performance, especially when the acquired firm is kept structurally separate. Analyses of large‐sample data of Indian DMNCs’ overseas acquisitions show that DMNCs’ light‐handed approach to managing acquisitions, despite acquiring majority ownership in them, seems suited to their acquisition objectives. © 2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.  相似文献   
152.
153.
Getting offshoring right   总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2  
Aron R  Singh JV 《Harvard business review》2005,83(12):135-43, 154
The prospect of offshoring and outsourcing business processes has captured the imagination of CEOs everywhere. In the past five years, a rising number of companies in North America and Europe have experimented with this strategy, hoping to reduce costs and gain strategic advantage. But many businesses have had mixed results. According to several studies, half the organizations that have shifted processes offshore have failed to generate the expected financial benefits. What's more, many of them have faced employee resistance and consumer dissatisfaction. Clearly, companies have to rethink how they formulate their offshoring strategies. A three-part methodology can help. First, companies need to prioritize their processes, ranking each based on two criteria: the value it creates for customers and the degree to which the company can capture some of that value. Companies will want to keep their core (highest-priority) processes in-house and consider outsourcing their commodity (low-priority) processes; critical (moderate-priority) processes are up for debate and must be considered carefully. Second, businesses should analyze all the risks that accompany offshoring and look systematically at their critical and commodity processes in terms of operational risk (the risk that processes won't operate smoothly after being offshored) and structural risk (the risk that relationships with service providers may not work as expected). Finally, companies should determine possible locations for their offshore efforts, as well as the organizational forms--such as captive centers and joint ventures--that those efforts might take. They can do so by examining each process's operational and structural risks side by side. This article outlines the tools that will help companies choose the right processes to offshore. It also describes a new organizational structure called the extended organization, in which companies specify the quality of services they want and work alongside providers to get that quality.  相似文献   
154.
This paper develops a dynamic model to analyze the development process in the agricultural sector. Formulated as a recursive linear programming model, it contains several commodities as outputs, farm and regional resource constraints on owned and purchased inputs-including working capital-and several farm sizes. The objective function is assumed to be separable for each farm size and additive for the region and measures for each year the net expected revenues from crop and livestock production less an investment charge. Prices are exogenous. The model is applied to a rapidly developing agricultural region in Southern Brazil and tested for its ability to trace regional farm sector development over a decade. It is then used to analyze the impact of alternative agricultural policies including price and credit subsidies.  相似文献   
155.
156.
157.
The generalization that island states are demographically more modern than continental states, and in particular that they have experienced greater fertility and mortality declines, is examined empirically for the Caribbean and the Pacific. A statistical analysis of recent Caribbean and Latin American data supports the view that island status is linked to an early demographic transition, independently of intervening, socio-economic factors, but the relationship is a modest one. The Pacific island data, however, tend to show the reverse, namely the persistence of high fertility despite favourable standards of living. One of the reasons for this contrast may be the greater importance of plantation agriculture and mass importation of labour in the Caribbean than in the Pacific.  相似文献   
158.
159.
160.
Implementation with partial verification   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
This paper examines the implementability of social choice functions when only partial verification of private information is possible. Green and Laffont (1986) used this framework to derive a necessary and sufficient condition for the revelation principle to continue to hold with partial verification. We provide economically interesting characterizations of this condition, which suggest that it may be too restrictive. This leads us to consider implementation (not necessarily truthful) in general, when there is partial verification. We consider the case where compensatory transfers are allowed, giving the mechanism designer further leeway. We show how partial verification may allow efficient implementation of bilateral trade, where it would otherwise not be possible. Received: 1 August 1998 / Accepted: 5 September 2000  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号