全文获取类型
收费全文 | 3798篇 |
免费 | 117篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 797篇 |
工业经济 | 289篇 |
计划管理 | 684篇 |
经济学 | 804篇 |
综合类 | 50篇 |
运输经济 | 53篇 |
旅游经济 | 118篇 |
贸易经济 | 665篇 |
农业经济 | 130篇 |
经济概况 | 323篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
邮电经济 | 1篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 28篇 |
2021年 | 18篇 |
2020年 | 52篇 |
2019年 | 90篇 |
2018年 | 82篇 |
2017年 | 107篇 |
2016年 | 76篇 |
2015年 | 59篇 |
2014年 | 85篇 |
2013年 | 485篇 |
2012年 | 111篇 |
2011年 | 127篇 |
2010年 | 124篇 |
2009年 | 141篇 |
2008年 | 152篇 |
2007年 | 107篇 |
2006年 | 108篇 |
2005年 | 94篇 |
2004年 | 108篇 |
2003年 | 117篇 |
2002年 | 111篇 |
2001年 | 98篇 |
2000年 | 107篇 |
1999年 | 86篇 |
1998年 | 87篇 |
1997年 | 85篇 |
1996年 | 74篇 |
1995年 | 89篇 |
1994年 | 57篇 |
1993年 | 45篇 |
1992年 | 43篇 |
1991年 | 52篇 |
1990年 | 55篇 |
1989年 | 41篇 |
1988年 | 34篇 |
1987年 | 35篇 |
1986年 | 39篇 |
1985年 | 63篇 |
1984年 | 56篇 |
1983年 | 42篇 |
1982年 | 63篇 |
1981年 | 36篇 |
1980年 | 40篇 |
1979年 | 41篇 |
1978年 | 32篇 |
1977年 | 21篇 |
1976年 | 23篇 |
1975年 | 14篇 |
1974年 | 16篇 |
1973年 | 16篇 |
排序方式: 共有3915条查询结果,搜索用时 14 毫秒
911.
Traditional tradeoff models of corporate capital structure, although still featured prominently in finance textbooks and widely accepted by practitioners, have been criticized by financial economists for doing a poor job of explaining observed debt ratios. Moreover, the observed ratios are far less stable than what would be predicted by the standard tradeoff models. In a study published several years ago in the Review of Financial Studies, the authors of this article aimed to shed more light on the underlying forces governing capital structure decisions by analyzing a set of major changes in capital structure in which companies initiated large increases in leverage through substantial new borrowings. They then attempted to explain why these companies chose to increase leverage and how their capital structures changed during the years after the large debt issues. As summarized in this article, the authors' findings indicate, first of all, that the large debt financings were used primarily to fund major corporate investments—and not, for example, to make large distributions to shareholders. And the changes in leverage ratios that came after the debt offerings were driven far more by the evolution of the companies' realized cash flows and their investment opportunities than by deliberate or decisive attempts to rebalance their capital structures toward a stationary target. In fact, many of the companies chose to take on even more debt when faced with cash‐flow deficits, despite operating with leverage that was already well above any reasonable estimate of their estimated target leverage. At the same time, companies that generated financial surpluses used them to reduce debt, even when their leverage had fallen well below their estimated targets. Taken as a whole, the findings of the authors' study support the idea that unused debt capacity represents an important source of financial flexibility, and that preserving such flexibility—and making use of it when valuable investment opportunities materialize—may well be the critical missing link in connecting capital structure theory with observed corporate behavior. 相似文献
912.
A model of tenure choice is presented which treats the benefits and costs of homeownership from a theory of finance perspective. The incremental benefits from homeownership over renting housing services are from two sources: protection against rental price risk (a forward transaction in the housing market) and from a possible capital gain from the eventual sale of a house (substitutes for portfolio investment). The cost of these benefits is higher initial outlay on housing, which reduces the funds available for portfolio investments. The comparative statics of this model is presented. It is shown that rental risk and portfolio risk add to the value of homeownership. Since homeownership is a partial substitute for portfolio investment, it is shown that the lower the covariance between portfolio returns and future home prices the more valuable is homeownership. In the presence of differential borrowing opportunities it is shown that the leverage available to housing significantly increases the value of homeownership. 相似文献
913.
Agri-environmental policies (AEPs) in the United States and the European Union are examples of payments for environmental services that pay farmers to reduce the negative externalities of agricultural production, while serving as a means to transfer public funds to farmers. We show that despite similar origins, AEPs in the two regions differ both in their specific objectives and in their implementation. For example, AEPs in most member states of the EU-15 have the additional objective of using agriculture as a driver for rural development. This objective is achieved by compensating farmers for the private delivery of positive public goods, such as attractive landscapes, produced by agriculture. The rationale is market failure, and there is empirical evidence that Europeans are willing to pay for such positive externalities. No comparable provision exists in U.S. policy. By contrast, U.S. AEPs focus almost entirely on reducing agriculture's negative externalities, such as soil erosion. Second, we find that U.S. programs are more targeted than their EU counterparts, and take opportunity cost into account. The EU programs, on the other hand, address a wider range of externalities, and are focused more on the paying for a particular farming process than reducing specific negative externalities. The EU takes a broader view of AEPs than does the United States, both in terms of type of activity that can be funded, and by using less targeting by land characteristics, and so the European program could be more easily used as a mechanism for transferring income to producers. Despite this, we find evidence that many of the amenities targeted by the programs are demanded by the population. 相似文献
914.
Thomas M. Lenard Monica M. Bettendorf Stephen Mcgonegal 《Journal of Regulatory Economics》1992,4(3):243-262
This paper discusses two external benchmarks for assessing the results of the 1990 postal rate proceeding. First, we generate stand-alone cost estimates for third-class bulk advertising mail, based on market data from private mail carriers. Second, we derive Ramsey optimal prices for all classes of mail. Private delivery costs for bulk advertising are significantly below the third-class bulk regular rates adopted by the U.S. Postal Rate Commission, indicating that the new third-class rates are well above stand-alone costs for an efficient enterprise. Moreover, the Ramsey price analysis suggests that the rate structure adopted reflects, at least implicitly, considerations other than economic efficiency. 相似文献
915.
916.
This study presents theoretical and empirical analyses of market size and consumer preference asymmetries to examine the implications of trade and trade policies for imperfectively competitive food manufacturing sectors. The results show that the effects of trade reforms on imperfectly competitive product trade are counter intuitive if a significant portion of food trade is attributed to market size and preference asymmetries. For example, countries with smaller market gain relatively more from trade liberalization than countries with larger markets because export market opportunities are greater for small countries than for large countries. 相似文献
917.
Ho Fai Chan Ahmed Skali David Stadelmann Benno Torgler Stephen Whyte 《Economics & Politics》2021,33(1):148-171
How are masculine‐looking politicians perceived by voters? Are these judgments accurate? We asked Australian survey participants to rate images of unknown‐to‐them Swiss politicians. We find that politicians with prominent markers of masculinity (including facial hair, baldness, and higher facial width‐to‐height ratio) are perceived as less honest and competent. To determine whether these perceptions correlate with political behavior, we exploit two unique features of Swiss politics. First, to check for politician–voter congruence, we match each politician's voting record to that of their constituents on identically worded legislative proposals. We find that bearded politicians are less likely to behave according to constituents' preferences. Second, by exploiting the mandatory disclosure of lobby group affiliations, we show that bearded politicians are less likely to be captured by interest groups. Our results suggest that more masculine‐looking politicians are recognized by both voters and lobby groups as less amenable to being controlled. 相似文献
918.
Stephen Haynes 《Economics Letters》1979,2(3):263-267
Empirical discrimination between ‘stock’ and ‘flow’ formulations of international investment based on regression tests has consistently proved unsuccessful. By applying the new technique of model discrimination in the frequency domain, this note provides unequivocal empirical support for the stock model. 相似文献
919.
Stephen C. Smearman Gerard E. D'souza Virgil J. Norton 《Environmental and Resource Economics》1997,10(2):167-175
Temperate hill-lands of the U.S.A. such as those in West Virginia are areas from which increasing output of farm-raised fish may be possible. However, the downstream economic impacts of current and projected future effluent as a result of aquaculture production have not been extensively studied. Using an externality framework and a combination of primary and secondary data, this study determines pollution prevention costs (PPC), and downstream pollution damage costs resulting from fish farm wastewater effluent measured as willingness to pay (WTP) for restoring water quality. PPC is estimated at $0.11 per kg of trout produced (which would add 6% to private production cost), and WTP is estimated at $0.49 per kg of trout produced (representing 25% of private production cost) at current production and price levels. This study shows that installation of filtration units is a low-cost (less than 6% of total cost) and an effective technology for controlling pollution at the source. Internalizing external costs (adding this 6% to private production costs) is one strategy that could contribute to sustainable growth of the aquaculture industry. 相似文献
920.
This study documents Australian firms' earnings management activities in response to product price controls established by the Australian government in the early 1970s. We predict that firms subject to price controls will adjust their discretionary accounting accruals downward to reduce reported net income and to increase the likelihood of approval of the requested price increase. To control for the confounding effect of performance, we analyse the performance of two groups of firms subject to price scrutiny prior to the event window and estimate the earnings management of these firms and a control group of firms during the period of scrutiny. Our results based on both longitudinal and a cross sectional experimental designs confirm that firms that were subject to the greatest scrutiny engaged in significant negative earnings management during the period of scrutiny, but not outside that period. Further, firms that were not subject to price controls did not engage in any significant earnings management during the same periods.
JEL classification: M41; M43 相似文献
JEL classification: M41; M43 相似文献