首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   200篇
  免费   14篇
财政金融   18篇
工业经济   7篇
计划管理   26篇
经济学   84篇
旅游经济   4篇
贸易经济   20篇
农业经济   14篇
经济概况   36篇
信息产业经济   5篇
  2021年   1篇
  2020年   6篇
  2019年   8篇
  2018年   7篇
  2017年   11篇
  2016年   9篇
  2015年   6篇
  2014年   8篇
  2013年   12篇
  2012年   7篇
  2011年   12篇
  2010年   12篇
  2009年   13篇
  2008年   11篇
  2007年   10篇
  2006年   19篇
  2005年   7篇
  2004年   7篇
  2003年   5篇
  2002年   1篇
  2000年   6篇
  1999年   2篇
  1998年   2篇
  1997年   6篇
  1996年   2篇
  1995年   4篇
  1993年   1篇
  1991年   1篇
  1990年   1篇
  1989年   1篇
  1988年   1篇
  1985年   1篇
  1982年   1篇
  1981年   1篇
  1979年   1篇
  1978年   1篇
  1976年   1篇
  1975年   2篇
  1973年   2篇
  1972年   1篇
  1971年   2篇
  1968年   2篇
排序方式: 共有214条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
31.
32.
A one-factor asset pricing model with an Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process as its state variable is studied under partial information: the mean-reverting level and the mean-reverting speed parameters are modeled as hidden/unobservable stochastic variables. No-arbitrage pricing formulas for derivative securities written on a liquid asset and exponential utility indifference pricing formulas for derivative securities written on an illiquid asset are presented. Moreover, a conditionally linear filtering result is introduced to compute the pricing/hedging formulas and the Bayesian estimators of the hidden variables.  相似文献   
33.
In Japan, some fishery cooperative associations use their fishery harbor names as a brand to differentiate their own shore fish. Most notable is the branding of mackerel. In this paper, we analyze the effects of branding using a discrete/continuous model. The results are as follows. First, there is first-mover advantage in the branding of mackerel. For instance, unlike other brands of mackerel, Seki-saba as the pioneering brand can increase its brand equity. Second, other brands have opposing effects that increase and decrease the brand equity of the pioneering brand. We find the former is strongest in the early stages of fishery branding when there are few competing brands of mackerel, while the latter becomes stronger in later stages when many other brands emerge.  相似文献   
34.
35.
36.
37.
This paper is a contribution to the study of the underlying mathematical structure of common-knowledge, which gives the well-known result of Aumann about the impossibility of ‘agreeing to disagree’. We present the Bayesian subjective probability model with player's belief: i.e. a triple (? %plane1D;4AF;, μ), in which i is a player. ? is a lattice in the field of sets of a state space Ω, %plane1D;4AF;, is a correspondence assigning to each state ω a filter %plane1D;4AF;(ω) in ?, and μ is a common-prior. For this model, we impose none of the important restrictions on the information structure in the Aumann-Bacharach model: axiom of knowledge K1. axiom of transparency K2 and axiom of wisdom K3. We can extend both the disagreement theorem of Aumann and the agreement theorem of Geanacoplos and Polemarchakis under the assumption that each ? is an Artinian lattice.  相似文献   
38.
In 1935 the Japanese economist Shibata criticized Böhm-Bawerk's discussion to deny the role of power on market and argued that the validity of Böhm-Bawerk's conclusion depends crucially on his special assumptions on the structure of production in his theory of interest. Unfortunately, both Böhm-Bawerk and Shibata used in their discussions an untenable supposition that the value of heterogeneous capital, which depends on values of endogenous variables, can be given exogenously. Our aim is to reconsider the problem in the light of a new interpretation of Böhm-Bawerk's theory of interest, which is free from this supposition.  相似文献   
39.
It is shown that, when a monopoly is present in a two-country, two-commodity world, the terms-of-trade do not necessarily fall in between the pre-trade relative prices of the two countries, and that these pre-trade prices do not unequivocally determine the pattern of trade.  相似文献   
40.
This paper constructs a new dataset of the industry‐specific real effective exchange rate, based on the producer price indices, for Japan, China, and Korea on a monthly basis from January 2001 to February 2013 in order to provide a better indicator for export price competitiveness. By conducting simulation analysis, we found that Korean electrical machinery firms substantially improved their cost competitiveness by lowering their production costs during the Korean won appreciation period, while Japanese firms' large plant investment caused by management misjudgments led to excessive production capacity, which resulted in the deterioration of Japanese export competitiveness. A structural vector autoregression analysis also reveals that industry differences of cost competitiveness as well as nominal exchange rate changes have significant impact on export performances of Japan and Korea.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号