首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   12759篇
  免费   245篇
财政金融   2455篇
工业经济   937篇
计划管理   2097篇
经济学   2655篇
综合类   102篇
运输经济   64篇
旅游经济   209篇
贸易经济   1934篇
农业经济   580篇
经济概况   1940篇
邮电经济   31篇
  2020年   124篇
  2019年   177篇
  2018年   200篇
  2017年   222篇
  2016年   222篇
  2015年   168篇
  2014年   249篇
  2013年   1317篇
  2012年   349篇
  2011年   374篇
  2010年   318篇
  2009年   324篇
  2008年   338篇
  2007年   294篇
  2006年   268篇
  2005年   251篇
  2004年   202篇
  2003年   235篇
  2002年   230篇
  2001年   218篇
  2000年   227篇
  1999年   247篇
  1998年   227篇
  1997年   202篇
  1996年   199篇
  1995年   188篇
  1994年   185篇
  1993年   215篇
  1992年   197篇
  1991年   198篇
  1990年   165篇
  1989年   176篇
  1988年   155篇
  1987年   145篇
  1986年   143篇
  1985年   256篇
  1984年   249篇
  1983年   229篇
  1982年   207篇
  1981年   199篇
  1980年   212篇
  1979年   205篇
  1978年   164篇
  1977年   178篇
  1976年   148篇
  1975年   140篇
  1974年   130篇
  1973年   138篇
  1971年   96篇
  1970年   94篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
71.
Proponents of state antitakeover legislation argue that previous empirical tests by financial economists of the wealth effects of Pennsylvania's 1990 antitakeover law are biased. We show that the proponents are correct. In particular, firm size, event-time clustering, and non-synchronous trading effects account for the wealth decreases reported in earlier studies. We also show, however, that both proponents and critics of the Pennsylvania legislation have ignored the earliest press release about it. The wealth effect associated with this announcement is negative, large, and statistically significant. These results therefore are consistent with the hypothesis that the Pennsylvania law decreased company values and with the hypothesis that the initial market reaction is an unbiased estimate of the law's effect on firm values.  相似文献   
72.
In search of the meaning of entrepreneurship   总被引:9,自引:0,他引:9  
This paper is an attempt to build a bridge between the popular and the academic usage of the terms entrepreneur and entrepreneurship, and to identify the raw materials needed to construct an interpretive framework capable of illuminating the nature of entrepreneurship and its role in economic theory. We review briefly the contributions made to this topic by Cantillon, Schumpeter, Schultz and Kirzner. We advance a synthetic definition of the entrepreneur as someone who specializes in taking responsibility for and making judgemental decisions that affect the location, the form, and the use of goods, resources, or institutions. We then conclude with some observations on the basic choice confronting economics regarding the place of entrepreneurship in economic analysis.  相似文献   
73.
Modern professionals are engaged in making things better, but the specific advances on the micro-level are increasingly undercut by problems on the macro-level. The content of this better is typically guided by values such as efficiency, productivity or cost-effectiveness, which are essentially output over input ratios unable to account for how a specific improvement will fit into the broader human, social and ecological contexts. Hence, micro-level advances lead to fragmentation and a loss of harmony, compatibility and conviviality. The situation is further complicated by the fact that, culturally speaking, science and technology have become good in themselves, making reasonable discourse difficult. This paper concludes with an analogy from an earlier epoch suggesting how the situation may be resolved. After completing a doctorate in Mechanical Engineering, Willem Vanderburg continued his studies of technology via the social sciences and humanities. He is currently the Director of the Centre for Technology and Social Development in the Faculty of Applied Science and Engineering at the University of Toronto. His publications include Technique and Culture, Vol. I, The Growth of Minds and Cultures (1985) and Perspectives on our Age (1981).  相似文献   
74.
Perhaps the greatest strategist of all time was not a business executive but a general. Helmuth von Moltke, chief of the Prussian and German general staffs from 1858 to 1888, issued "directives" to his officers rather than specific commands. These guidelines for autonomous decision making encouraged Moltke's subordinates to show individual initiative. In this article, Hans Hinterhuber and Wolfgang Popp translate Moltke's example into business terms. According to Moltke, strategy is applied common sense and cannot be taught. The authors suggest that good entrepreneurs and managers--along with generals--are born with the qualities that make them successful. But even if managers have the potential to be good strategists, they must develop and hone their natural talents. And CEOs and top management can help by identifying and promoting such talents in their employees. Hinterhuber and Popp have created a questionnaire that helps measure strategic management competence. Managers and entrepreneurs take this test themselves, answering ten questions such as, "Do I have an entrepreneurial vision?", "Do I have a corporate philosophy?", and "Do I have competitive advantages?" Using the questionnaire, company management can evaluate managers being considered for a promotion. At the same time, those who take the test can use it to determine their own performance as strategists. Strategic managers provide subordinates with general guidelines, just as Helmuth von Moltke issued directives to his officers. And outstanding entrepreneurs create a corporate culture in which their vision, philosophy, and business strategies are implemented by employees who think independently.  相似文献   
75.
76.
77.
Goldberg JH 《Medical economics》1992,69(4):162-6, 169-70, 172-5
  相似文献   
78.
79.
80.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号