首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   3657篇
  免费   178篇
财政金融   815篇
工业经济   283篇
计划管理   513篇
经济学   709篇
综合类   27篇
运输经济   86篇
旅游经济   279篇
贸易经济   790篇
农业经济   61篇
经济概况   265篇
邮电经济   7篇
  2024年   6篇
  2023年   40篇
  2022年   25篇
  2021年   40篇
  2020年   89篇
  2019年   137篇
  2018年   177篇
  2017年   181篇
  2016年   154篇
  2015年   99篇
  2014年   164篇
  2013年   645篇
  2012年   186篇
  2011年   187篇
  2010年   178篇
  2009年   173篇
  2008年   137篇
  2007年   105篇
  2006年   70篇
  2005年   84篇
  2004年   82篇
  2003年   89篇
  2002年   100篇
  2001年   57篇
  2000年   40篇
  1999年   47篇
  1998年   44篇
  1997年   32篇
  1996年   38篇
  1995年   39篇
  1994年   33篇
  1993年   34篇
  1992年   28篇
  1991年   35篇
  1990年   14篇
  1989年   17篇
  1988年   18篇
  1987年   15篇
  1986年   19篇
  1985年   17篇
  1984年   12篇
  1983年   21篇
  1982年   19篇
  1981年   16篇
  1980年   13篇
  1979年   15篇
  1978年   9篇
  1977年   14篇
  1973年   10篇
  1971年   5篇
排序方式: 共有3835条查询结果,搜索用时 464 毫秒
931.
In order to provide an effective whistle-blowing system, it is expected that companies would provide employees with a high level of disclosure regarding the whistle-blowing process. This study investigates variation in the extent of whistle-blowing disclosures. As a measure of whistle-blowing implementation, this study further examines the provision of a hotline channel. The results suggest that the extent of whistle-blowing disclosures is positively associated with the permissibility of anonymous reporting and organisational support for whistle-blowing, the number of external directors on the audit committee, and the existence of concentrated shareholdings. The mere existence of whistle-blowing disclosures could simply be symbolic. The findings also indicate a greater likelihood of the provision of hotlines when companies are larger in size, have a higher level of current inventory, are cross-listed in the US, and permit anonymous reporting.  相似文献   
932.
933.
934.
The central objective of this paper is to empirically evaluate the degree of linkages among East Asian equity and bond markets. Using data from the IMF’s Coordinated Portfolio Investment Survey (CPIS), we find that intra‐East Asian financial asset holdings of four East Asian countries – Japan, Korea, Hong Kong and Singapore – are larger than the levels predicted by the financial gravity model. However, our analysis suggests that this result is likely to be driven by intra‐regional trade linkages and reflect those linkages. Therefore, the salient implication for regional policymakers is that they should continue to promote intra‐regional financial integration. This paper also aims to analyse the impact of three different types of country‐specific risks – political, economic and financial risks – on investment from the four countries. This analysis yields a clear positive relationship between destination‐country risk, in particular political risk, and capital inflows.  相似文献   
935.
Despite the importance of knowledge sharing in competitive environments, there is a paucity of studies examining the relationship between employee knowledge sharing and work–family conflict. Drawing on insights from conservation of resources theory, this study investigated how employees may reduce their knowledge-sharing behaviors when they experience resources lost from work interference with family (WIF) or family interference with work (FIW). Furthermore, the role of supervisor support in the relationship among WIF, FIW and knowledge sharing was explored as a valuable resource. Using data collected from 159 employees in South Korea, we found support that WIF is negatively related to knowledge sharing. In addition, the role of supervisor support in the relationship among WIF, FIW and knowledge sharing was the strongest when WIF is low and FIW is high, thus supporting the hypothesized a three-way effect. Theoretical and practical implications are discussed.  相似文献   
936.
937.
938.
939.
Why is the economic growth rate so low in poor countries? This paper offers an explanation by using a simple two‐sector AK growth model with intersectoral linkages and high relative prices of intermediate goods. Intersectoral linkages lead to two balanced growth paths (BGPs). The high‐growth BGP is a source. The low‐growth BGP is a sink because it has a small final goods sector, small intersectoral spillovers from the final goods sector to the intermediate goods sector, and small marginal products in the intermediate goods sector, yielding high relative prices of intermediate goods. The low‐growth BGP is an attractor and thus development trap. To produce a big push effect, this paper analyzes the first‐best policy and finds that a subsidy to own consumption and a provision of public goods to the final goods sector can internalize the external effect and render the low‐growth BGP infeasible. As a result, there is only the high‐growth BGP.  相似文献   
940.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号