首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   1366篇
  免费   11篇
财政金融   284篇
工业经济   103篇
计划管理   231篇
经济学   286篇
综合类   19篇
运输经济   22篇
旅游经济   43篇
贸易经济   241篇
农业经济   65篇
经济概况   83篇
  2024年   9篇
  2023年   15篇
  2022年   9篇
  2021年   21篇
  2020年   28篇
  2019年   42篇
  2018年   48篇
  2017年   53篇
  2016年   58篇
  2015年   32篇
  2014年   50篇
  2013年   151篇
  2012年   56篇
  2011年   53篇
  2010年   82篇
  2009年   60篇
  2008年   67篇
  2007年   51篇
  2006年   40篇
  2005年   38篇
  2004年   44篇
  2003年   34篇
  2002年   39篇
  2001年   24篇
  2000年   35篇
  1999年   21篇
  1998年   24篇
  1997年   20篇
  1996年   14篇
  1995年   19篇
  1994年   22篇
  1993年   9篇
  1992年   13篇
  1991年   9篇
  1990年   18篇
  1989年   6篇
  1988年   6篇
  1987年   5篇
  1986年   4篇
  1985年   4篇
  1984年   6篇
  1983年   6篇
  1982年   5篇
  1980年   7篇
  1979年   4篇
  1978年   3篇
  1977年   3篇
  1973年   2篇
  1972年   1篇
  1971年   4篇
排序方式: 共有1377条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
31.
This paper examines the role of the no-arbitrage condition in financial markets with heterogeneous expectations. We consider a single-period, state-contingent claims model, withM risky securities andS states. There exist two types of heterogeneously informed investors, where the information heterogeneity is defined with respect to either the security payoff matrix, the state probability vector, or state partitions. When the information heterogeneity is defined with respect to either the security payoff matrix or state partitions, the no-arbitrage condition imposes a constraint on the dispersion of information between informed and uninformed investors. Further, the no-arbitrage condition is useful in ascertaining the patterns of heterogeneity among investors that are consistent with equilibrium. However, when the information heterogeneity is defined with respect to state probabilities, the role of the no-arbitrage condition is severely restricted. Finally, the no-arbitrage condition may have important implications for the (necessary and sufficient) conditions for the existence of an equilibrium price vector in financial markets with heterogeneous expectations.  相似文献   
32.
A labor market model is used to estimate elasticities between various disamenity factors of urban areas and the wage in those areas. The results are used to calculate a correction to the personal income (PI) data for use in the construction of an index to be used as a measure of economic welfare. The labor supply equation of the model includes some population-related variables which Tobin and Nordhaus have hypothesized represent disamenities of urban living. The labor demand equation is derived from a production function which includes a measure of agglomeration economies. A two-stage least-squares regression analysis provides results which indicate that the hypothesized factors are actually amenity factors. The resulting correction to the personal income data is thus an addition: Economic welfare is higher than that indicated by the PI statistics.  相似文献   
33.
Enterprise resource planning (ERP) implementation projects often fail to achieve their objectives. These often problematic projects are frequently the setting for intense and growing power struggles. Existing studies (e.g., Boonstra, 2006; Shepherd, Clegg, & Stride, 2009) have provided researchers with insights about issues of power in these projects. However, existing research has yet to provide a comprehensive picture of power in these projects or insights on how this picture changes with the passage of time. Clegg's (1989) circuits of power framework provides a useful tool for developing this needed comprehensive picture. We use the circuits of power framework as a tool for categorizing existing literature on power in ERP implementations. More importantly, we draw on this framework to provide a comprehensive view of power in the particular context of these projects. Specifically, we analyze the power relations during the implementation of an ERP in an organization. We do so by identifying how disturbances to the circuits of power – power struggles – arise and intensify during the implementation of the ERP. In this way, our work makes both a theoretical and an empirical contribution to the study of power in ERP implementation projects.  相似文献   
34.
Within a sample of 109 developing countries for the period 1975–2014 and controlling for country and time-fixed effects, this article presents evidence that workers’ remittances are more effective in promoting growth in developing countries with strong democratic institutions. The evidence is robust to alternative samples and different measures of democratic institutions.  相似文献   
35.
From the previous literature, it can be found that consumers tend to undervalue discounted future energy costs in their purchase decisions for energy-using durables. We show that this finding could, in part, result from ignoring consumer heterogeneity in empirical analyses as opposed to true undervaluation.  相似文献   
36.
To market important products to families successfully, salespeople must understand how couples behave in concert to resolve conflict across major decisions. The authors develop a model of spousal fairness and test it with a study of multi-period family purchase decision making. The results show that a spousal sense of fairness serves as a mechanism for contemporary couples to harmonize conflict over time in family decisions. Specifically, spouses’ perceived fairness mediates the relationship between spousal prior influence and spousal decision behavior in subsequent decisions. Spouses also consider their partner’s perceptions of fairness when taking action to restore fairness. Moreover, the effects of perceived fairness are moderated by spousal traits of empathy, egalitarianism, and empowerment in a gendered pattern.
Julie Juan LiEmail:
  相似文献   
37.
This paper sets out a methodology for constructing fan charts for the government deficit and debt ratios over the medium term. It relies on information contained in Stability/Convergence Programme Updates, a model of the relevant stochastic process (for example, that of real GDP) or processes, and a parameter estimate of the sensitivity of the primary budget balance to the output gap for the member state under consideration. A model of the dynamic deficit–debt relationship allows the impact of random output growth to work its way through the fiscal arithmetic in a consistent and traceable way to produce fan charts over a five‐year forecast horizon. The initial set of fiscal fan charts included here for Ireland use the indicative public finance projections set out in its 2011 Update. The methodology makes the standard assumption of no fiscal policy response to any change in the budgetary position over the period such as could arise from changes in growth rates. Governments will, however, generally be in a position to adjust fiscal policy towards meeting a specific target, such as the 3 per cent Maastricht Treaty deficit target. A second set of fan charts is included that indicates how the probabilistic range of fiscal outcomes could be affected by a tightening of fiscal policy in 2013–15.  相似文献   
38.
Wong  Kevin Tze-wai  Zheng  Victor  Wan  Po-san 《Quality and Quantity》2022,56(4):2387-2414
Quality & Quantity - In recent years, rapid increases in mobile phone ownership and decreases in landline users have led to potential biases in landline phone survey estimations. Mobile-only...  相似文献   
39.
40.
Kevin S. Nell 《Applied economics》2013,45(13):1431-1444
This study emphasizes the importance of identifying the origin of inflation in the present context of inflation targeting by many emerging market and transition economies. The analysis shows, based on South African data, how structural (supply) and demand inflation can be distinguished. The results indicate that South Africa's inflation experience between 1973q1 and 1998q4 is characterized by two monetary regimes. During the first regime (1973q1–1984q4) the long-run cause of inflation is demand-pull. The second regime (1987q1–1998q4) represents major changes to structural (‘imported’) and cost-push inflation. The two-year period 1985–1986 signifies structural change from the first to the second regime. Moreover, the results in the second regime remain robust when the inflation model is subjected to ‘new’ out-of-sample data until 2001q2. Evidence of structural (‘imported’) inflation in the second regime suggests that inflation should not entirely be squeezed out of the system nor should it necessarily be kept at the lowest possible level, because some inflation may be regarded as the natural by-product of the growth and development process. South Africa's inflation experience points to several lessons for existing (and potential) emerging market and transition economies with some form of inflation targeting.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号