首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   2957篇
  免费   113篇
  国内免费   25篇
财政金融   291篇
工业经济   250篇
计划管理   765篇
经济学   593篇
综合类   208篇
运输经济   37篇
旅游经济   53篇
贸易经济   478篇
农业经济   140篇
经济概况   275篇
信息产业经济   1篇
邮电经济   4篇
  2024年   4篇
  2023年   31篇
  2022年   41篇
  2021年   103篇
  2020年   84篇
  2019年   64篇
  2018年   69篇
  2017年   72篇
  2016年   74篇
  2015年   99篇
  2014年   144篇
  2013年   242篇
  2012年   210篇
  2011年   253篇
  2010年   217篇
  2009年   203篇
  2008年   226篇
  2007年   187篇
  2006年   165篇
  2005年   124篇
  2004年   67篇
  2003年   38篇
  2002年   34篇
  2001年   42篇
  2000年   28篇
  1999年   19篇
  1998年   14篇
  1997年   20篇
  1996年   14篇
  1995年   15篇
  1994年   10篇
  1993年   14篇
  1992年   20篇
  1991年   12篇
  1990年   7篇
  1989年   6篇
  1988年   8篇
  1986年   7篇
  1985年   12篇
  1984年   16篇
  1983年   8篇
  1982年   8篇
  1981年   9篇
  1980年   7篇
  1979年   4篇
  1978年   4篇
  1977年   5篇
  1975年   9篇
  1974年   4篇
  1971年   3篇
排序方式: 共有3095条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
941.
We propose a dynamic model of an oligopoly industry characterized by spatial competition between multi‐store retailers. Firms compete in prices and decide where to open or close stores depending on demand and cost conditions, the number of competitors at different locations, and on location‐specific private‐information shocks. The model distinguishes multiple forces in the spatial configuration of store networks, such as cannibalization of revenue between stores of the same retail chain, economies of density, competition, consumer transportation costs, or positive demand spillovers from other stores. We develop an algorithm to approximate a Markov Perfect Equilibrium in our model, and propose a procedure for the estimation of the parameters of the model using panel data on number of stores, prices, and quantities at multiple geographic locations within a city. We also present a numerical example to illustrate the model and algorithm.  相似文献   
942.
943.
944.
We compare 330 ARCH‐type models in terms of their ability to describe the conditional variance. The models are compared out‐of‐sample using DM–$ exchange rate data and IBM return data, where the latter is based on a new data set of realized variance. We find no evidence that a GARCH(1,1) is outperformed by more sophisticated models in our analysis of exchange rates, whereas the GARCH(1,1) is clearly inferior to models that can accommodate a leverage effect in our analysis of IBM returns. The models are compared with the test for superior predictive ability (SPA) and the reality check for data snooping (RC). Our empirical results show that the RC lacks power to an extent that makes it unable to distinguish ‘good’ and ‘bad’ models in our analysis. Copyright © 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.  相似文献   
945.
L. K. C. Chan (1983) and R. B. Barsky et al. (1986) have demonstrated that a tax cut financed by bonds to be repaid from proportional income taxes on uncertain future income, by reducing the latter's riskiness, stimulates current consumption - Ricardian equivalence does not hold. However, their two-period models exclude the possibility that future taxes are uncertain. In this paper a three-period model is developed that, by allowing the government two periods in which to collect taxes, introduces ex ante tax rate uncertainty. This renders the result concerning Ricardian equivalence ambiguous. By comparison, taxes levied as lump sums and via a ‘lottery’ respectively produce the ‘usual’ effects (zero and negative) on consumption.  相似文献   
946.
This paper takes a wide-ranging transnational look, within the frame of he European Union, at the differences between large and small firms based on practices of flexibility. More specifically, the research aims to evaluate whether small firms form a homogeneous body in applying flexible practices as opposed to large firms, as well as observing the differential effects on performance when there are discrepancies in the coalignment levels between a firm's actual flexibility and that required by the environment. The hypotheses are tested using data from 417 European firms. The results reveal that (1) good coalignments between actual and required flexibility (flexibility fit) have a greater influence on business performance in the case of small firms; (2) there are significant differences between small and large firms as regards operative flexibility, strategic flexibility, financial flexibility (organizational slack), and performance. The large firms analyzed coalign their flexibility fit better in their various dimensions (structural, operative, and strategic); (3) the degree of metaflexibility can be greater among small firms, which represents a greater information processing capacity, thus enabling the flexibility fit to be constantly coaligned to changes in the environment. However, a greater metaflexibility is not immediately reflected in the flexibility fit; and (4) this greater flexibility fit among large firms can be favored by their greater financial flexibility.  相似文献   
947.
The purpose of this paper is to highlight and discuss recent developments in the worldwide use of anti‐dumping (AD) policy as a possible strategic counterpoint to trade liberalisation. First, we review briefly the original intended purpose of AD policy, and reflect on its secondary position on the agenda of current international trade negotiations. Second, we discuss the escalating – and perhaps strategic – use of AD policy, particularly in the developing world, and highlight the roles of both interest groups and the state in determining policy outcomes. Next, we review the state of affairs of AD policy with the world's most active user, the US. In particular, we introduce and discuss the latest important development, the implementation of the ‘Continued Dumping and Subsidy Offset Act of 2000’, which incorporates monetary compensation for petitioners, potentially offering more opportunities for strategic policy behaviour by firms, industries and the state. We conclude the article with a short discussion of directions for future research and some general concerns about the use of AD policy.  相似文献   
948.
Conclusion Subsequent rounds of multilateral tariff reductions and changes in the GSP and other trade arrangements supersede the analysis presented here, but this study still provides some guidance to future analysis of tariff concessions. The review of the literature suggests a need for greater precision in methods and data. The new technique employed here would appear to be appropriate for future analyses of multilateral trade liberalization and of proliferating free trade areas. Our results indicate that extremely optimistic and pessimistic estimates of GSP trade effects should be regarded with skepticism. The GSP has probably had a modest positive impact on LDC exports to the United States.  相似文献   
949.
950.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号