首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   325篇
  免费   11篇
财政金融   34篇
工业经济   12篇
计划管理   59篇
经济学   96篇
综合类   2篇
贸易经济   91篇
农业经济   5篇
经济概况   24篇
邮电经济   13篇
  2023年   1篇
  2022年   2篇
  2021年   1篇
  2020年   6篇
  2019年   5篇
  2018年   13篇
  2017年   8篇
  2016年   15篇
  2015年   12篇
  2014年   15篇
  2013年   29篇
  2012年   15篇
  2011年   29篇
  2010年   19篇
  2009年   18篇
  2008年   15篇
  2007年   7篇
  2006年   18篇
  2005年   14篇
  2004年   12篇
  2003年   20篇
  2002年   13篇
  2001年   7篇
  2000年   2篇
  1999年   6篇
  1998年   2篇
  1997年   4篇
  1996年   4篇
  1995年   2篇
  1994年   1篇
  1992年   1篇
  1991年   2篇
  1979年   1篇
  1973年   3篇
  1972年   3篇
  1971年   4篇
  1970年   4篇
  1969年   2篇
  1878年   1篇
排序方式: 共有336条查询结果,搜索用时 203 毫秒
151.
This is a model of a contest where, in order to win, each opponent can use two instruments. The probabilities of winning are explored, as well as the expenditures of the interest groups, and the relative rent-dissipation in both cases where the players have the option to use only one instrument (the standard Tullock contest) and where the players have the option to use two instruments in the contest. We show that the use of two instruments strengthens the player with the higher stake, decreases the relative rent dissipation and it decreases total expenditure if the parties are sufficiently asymmetric. Received: February 23, 2001 / Accepted: March 25, 2002 RID="*" ID="*" We are grateful to two anonymous referees and the editor Kai Konrad, for constructive comments.  相似文献   
152.
153.
154.
155.
156.
In 1998, the National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) in the published industrial statistics modified the scope of enterprises covered and the enterprise classification system. This paper highlights the modifications and identifies two implications. First, the use of a proportional allocation rule in data aggregation boosts the size of “public ownership,” an important cornerstone of socialism. Second, the switch from compiling detailed statistics on enterprises identified by an administrative criterion to enterprises that exceed a fixed volume of sales revenue poses new difficulties for comparative data analysis but also represents a change in statistical practice that may yet lead to data of better quality.  相似文献   
157.
We study the optimal choice of exchange rate regime when agents have beliefs that are mutually inconsistent. A general framework for identifying optimal policies in such situations is proposed and then used to compare fixed and floating exchange rate regimes. Agents are assumed to have diverse rational beliefs (rather than rational expectations), implying the prevalence of (rational) overconfidence. We argue that in such a situation, in comparing economic institutions, one should employ the concept of ex‐post optimality rather than that of Pareto optimality. Fixing the exchange rate is ex‐post optimal because it eliminates mistaken actions (based on mistaken beliefs).  相似文献   
158.
159.
Customer profitability measurement is an important element in customer relationship management and a lever for enhanced marketing accountability. Two distinct measurement approaches have emerged in the marketing literature: Customer Lifetime Value (CLV) and Customer Profitability Analysis (CPA). Myriad models have been demonstrated within these two approaches across industries. However, limited efforts have been made to explain when sophisticated CLV or CPA models will be most useful. This paper explores the advantages and limitations of sophisticated CLV and CPA models and proposes that the degree of sophistication deployed when implementing customer profitability measurement models is determined by the type of complexity encountered in firms’ customer environments. This gives rise to a contingency framework for customer profitability measurement model selection and five research propositions. Additionally, the framework provides design and implementation guidance for managers seeking to implement customer profitability measurement models for resource allocation purposes.  相似文献   
160.
The German Federal Government aims at increasing the use of biomethane to 6 billion cubic meters per year by 2020. The German Act on the Promotion of Renewable Energies in the Heat Sector (Renewable Heat Act ?C EEW?rmeG) of 2009 has paved the way for renewable energies in the heating market with 14?% in 2020 being the ultimate goal. Biomethane is one of the options provided in the EEW?rmeG. Building owners can choose between different renewable energy sources as well as a range of compensatory measures such as district heating, insulation or combined heat and power. However, they do not make this decision independently but together with other members of a buying center that comprises architects, specialist consultants and installers. These other members are pursuing their own interests, which includes maximizing their contract volume. Moreover the owner takes his decision under incomplete information. Both factors are detrimental to an optimal decision. Biomethane is chosen for only 3?% of newly constructed buildings. For a better understanding of why the use of biomethane for heating purposes is so limited, the authors have developed an economic calculation method that compares different renewable energy sources as well as compensatory measures. For a single-family home, biomethane is the least attractive option from a financial perspective; for a multi-family house, on the other hand, it ranks third. In order to promote the utilization of biomethane and to achieve the 6 billion cubic meter/year goal by 2020, the Federal Government needs to open up the options for biomethane beyond the now mandatory cogeneration solution. Moreover, the EEW?rmeG, which applies to newly built houses only, should be expanded to existing buildings.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号