全文获取类型
收费全文 | 17786篇 |
免费 | 395篇 |
国内免费 | 1篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 3413篇 |
工业经济 | 1323篇 |
计划管理 | 2954篇 |
经济学 | 3799篇 |
综合类 | 159篇 |
运输经济 | 129篇 |
旅游经济 | 276篇 |
贸易经济 | 2935篇 |
农业经济 | 754篇 |
经济概况 | 2383篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
邮电经济 | 56篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 144篇 |
2020年 | 220篇 |
2019年 | 323篇 |
2018年 | 346篇 |
2017年 | 406篇 |
2016年 | 402篇 |
2015年 | 289篇 |
2014年 | 438篇 |
2013年 | 1719篇 |
2012年 | 563篇 |
2011年 | 569篇 |
2010年 | 512篇 |
2009年 | 550篇 |
2008年 | 512篇 |
2007年 | 473篇 |
2006年 | 427篇 |
2005年 | 399篇 |
2004年 | 341篇 |
2003年 | 359篇 |
2002年 | 354篇 |
2001年 | 347篇 |
2000年 | 331篇 |
1999年 | 348篇 |
1998年 | 321篇 |
1997年 | 280篇 |
1996年 | 274篇 |
1995年 | 257篇 |
1994年 | 248篇 |
1993年 | 256篇 |
1992年 | 251篇 |
1991年 | 251篇 |
1990年 | 204篇 |
1989年 | 220篇 |
1988年 | 190篇 |
1987年 | 174篇 |
1986年 | 183篇 |
1985年 | 318篇 |
1984年 | 304篇 |
1983年 | 286篇 |
1982年 | 256篇 |
1981年 | 237篇 |
1980年 | 256篇 |
1979年 | 247篇 |
1978年 | 217篇 |
1977年 | 225篇 |
1976年 | 184篇 |
1975年 | 174篇 |
1974年 | 169篇 |
1973年 | 157篇 |
1972年 | 111篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 12 毫秒
961.
962.
963.
Getting the attention you need 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Employees have an enormous amount of business information at their fingertips--more specifically, at their desktops. The floodgates are open; profitable possibilities abound. But having to handle all that information has pushed downsized staffs to the brink of an acute attention deficit disorder. To achieve corporate goals, business leaders need their employees' full attention--and that attention is in short supply. Authors Thomas Davenport and John Beck have studied how companies manage the attention of their employees and their site visitors. In this article, they analyze the components of attention management through three lenses--economic, psychobiological, and technological--and offer guidelines for keeping employees focused on crucial corporate tasks. Their lessons are drawn from the best practices employed by today's stickiest Web sites and by traditional attention industries such as advertising, film, and television. The authors say executives must manage attention knowing that it's a zero-sum game (there's only so much to go around). Managers should also consider capitalizing on the basic survival and competitive instincts we all have that help determine how much attention we pay to certain things. For instance, the threat of corporate demise--and the consequent loss of jobs and livelihoods--undoubtedly focuses workers' attention on the need to change. Likewise, internal competition among business units may give employees added incentive to pay attention to a profit or sales goal. Leaders today need to pay more attention to attention because it's widely misunderstood and widely mismanaged, the authors conclude. 相似文献
964.
Pascal Frantz Norvald Instefjord Martin Walker 《Journal of Business Finance & Accounting》2013,40(9-10):1184-1220
Recent public policy debates have led to increased calls for full transparency of executive compensation. However, in practice, many firms are reluctant to disclose the full details of how they link executive compensation to performance. One possible reason for lack of full disclosure is that managers use their power to hide the details of their compensation plan in order to disguise opportunistic rent extraction. If this is the reason for secrecy, then public policy designed to force firms to provide full disclosure is unlikely to be resisted by shareholders. However, another possible explanation for less than full transparency is that some degree of secrecy about executive compensation may be in the interest of the company and its shareholders. If this explanation is correct, then public policy moves to increase transparency may be met by counter moves designed to protect managers and shareholders from such policies. In this paper we investigate if full disclosure of executive compensation arrangements is always optimal for shareholders. We develop a model where optimal executive remuneration solves a moral hazard problem. However, the degree to which the moral hazard problem affects the shareholders depends on hidden information, so that disclosure of the executive compensation scheme will typically reveal the hidden information, which can be harmful to shareholders. The model derives, therefore, the optimal disclosure policy and the optimal remuneration scheme. We find that the shareholders are better off pre‐committing not to disclose the executive compensation scheme whenever possible. Executive directors are shown to be better off too in the absence of disclosure of executive compensation schemes. An argument for mandating disclosure is that it provides better information to shareholders but our analysis demonstrates that disclosure does not necessarily achieve this objective. The results suggest that less than full disclosure can be in the interest of shareholders, the reason for this being that disclosures cannot be made selectively to shareholders but will also be made to strategic opponents. This will be the case if the board of directors and the remuneration committee includes enough independent directors. Whether or not non‐disclosure to shareholders is in their interest is however an empirical matter involving a trade‐off between the proprietary costs associated with disclosure to shareholders and the costs of potential collusion between executive and non‐executive directors associated with non‐disclosure. 相似文献
965.
Arford PH 《Nursing economic$》2005,23(2):72-7, 55
Dysfunctional nurse-physician communication has been linked to medication errors, patient injuries, and patient deaths. The organization is accountable for providing a context that supports effective nurse-physician communication. Organizational strategies to create such a context are synthesized from the structural, human resource, political, and cultural frameworks of organizational behavior. 相似文献
966.
Gerald H. Lander 《International Advances in Economic Research》2006,12(4):475-490
I investigate the mean reversion tendency of small growth stocks. Using a carefully articulated research design employing established and empirically tested principles, my findings should support or refute the anecdotal evidence that small growth stocks make superior investments. The primary motivation for the study springs from the documented differential preference among investors for value and growth stocks. Despite evidence that value stocks tend to outperform growth stocks, investors retain strong interest in growth stocks. Yet in examining the performance of Business Week’s (BW), smaller capitalization companies (called “Hot Growth Companies”) with respect to the overall financial market, Bauman et al. [2002] found positive excess returns in the pre-publication period but negative excess returns in the post-publication period. A limitation of their study is that their analyses relied on only three criteria: sales, BW rank and return on capital, which do not represent completely a firm’s financial health. I replicate Bauman et al.’s study but use a more robust and representative variable set to test the mean reversal hypothesis — Forbes’ financial criteria — and I focus on six variables. In the current study, I look at 4,200 companies listed in Forbes from 1980 to 2000. The results of the expanded study substantiate Bauman et al.’s [2002] study showing that there are positive excess returns in the pre-publication period, but negative excess returns in the post-publication period. An expanded future study will look at five additional variables to see if they make a significant difference on the effects of the returns of small growth stocks. 相似文献
967.
The “Deep Roots” literature investigates the effects of ancient cultural variables on economic outcomes. We extend Putterman and Weil’s (Q J Econ 125(4):1627–1682, 2010) inquiry into the effects of State History and Agricultural History to the economic output in ethnically and racially diverse fifty U.S. States. The ethnic and racial differences across the populations of the fifty U.S. states vary considerably due to historical immigration and slave flows that, as a result, produced radically different State History and Agricultural History scores across the states. Results derived from Putterman and Weil’s methodology do not robustly predict per capita levels of economic output across U.S. States. We also investigate the institutions channel, and find that they impact some measures of institutions, but they do not impact the quality of economic institutions which may be essential for promoting economic growth and development. 相似文献
968.
Summary Pseudo Bayesian estimators for the variance components based on Jeffrey’s Rule are derived for the mixed balanced incomplete
block design and are compared with the usual analysis of variance estimators in terms of mean squared error (MSE) efficiency.
Numerical results show that Pseudo-Bayesian estimators are more efficient in numerical results. 相似文献
969.
Stephan M. Wagner Author Vitae Martin Hoegl Author Vitae 《Industrial Marketing Management》2006,35(8):936-943
While there is increasing evidence that involving suppliers in new product development (NPD) is important, and for many firms even inevitable, there is also evidence that not all such efforts are successful. Firms aiming at implementing this strategy effectively have to pay close attention to several contingency factors on the organizational level and properly manage supplier involvement on the project level. The exploratory case study research underlying this article explores key issues to be considered when involving suppliers in NPD and the counter measures they can take. Our research shows that companies differentiate between so-called “know-how” and “capacity” projects, and that they manage them differently. Furthermore, this research shows that firms outside the automotive and high-tech manufacturing industries are likely to intensify supplier involvement in the future. 相似文献
970.
Using data on job approval ratings of governors, U.S. senators, and the president, we find that firms located in states with high approval ratings outperform firms located in states with low approval ratings by .64% per month. Furthermore, this relationship is stronger when investors are actively involved in politics, when local politicians are closer to the center of political power, for small firms that have a larger proportion of local investors, and for financially strong areas where investors are ready to execute investments in local stocks. Overall, our study shows that investors’ political sentiment is important in determining stock returns. 相似文献