全文获取类型
收费全文 | 10076篇 |
免费 | 305篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2077篇 |
工业经济 | 1009篇 |
计划管理 | 1775篇 |
经济学 | 2083篇 |
综合类 | 88篇 |
运输经济 | 126篇 |
旅游经济 | 202篇 |
贸易经济 | 1680篇 |
农业经济 | 547篇 |
经济概况 | 791篇 |
邮电经济 | 3篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 62篇 |
2021年 | 82篇 |
2020年 | 166篇 |
2019年 | 236篇 |
2018年 | 243篇 |
2017年 | 258篇 |
2016年 | 241篇 |
2015年 | 189篇 |
2014年 | 278篇 |
2013年 | 1177篇 |
2012年 | 328篇 |
2011年 | 366篇 |
2010年 | 326篇 |
2009年 | 414篇 |
2008年 | 403篇 |
2007年 | 339篇 |
2006年 | 349篇 |
2005年 | 303篇 |
2004年 | 287篇 |
2003年 | 305篇 |
2002年 | 278篇 |
2001年 | 236篇 |
2000年 | 235篇 |
1999年 | 213篇 |
1998年 | 197篇 |
1997年 | 209篇 |
1996年 | 169篇 |
1995年 | 169篇 |
1994年 | 158篇 |
1993年 | 150篇 |
1992年 | 132篇 |
1991年 | 128篇 |
1990年 | 116篇 |
1989年 | 104篇 |
1988年 | 92篇 |
1987年 | 103篇 |
1986年 | 76篇 |
1985年 | 122篇 |
1984年 | 145篇 |
1983年 | 133篇 |
1982年 | 114篇 |
1981年 | 87篇 |
1980年 | 97篇 |
1979年 | 85篇 |
1978年 | 67篇 |
1977年 | 65篇 |
1976年 | 62篇 |
1975年 | 36篇 |
1974年 | 52篇 |
1973年 | 45篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
31.
David Etherington 《Local Economy》1987,2(1):31-37
In this continuing discussion on the role of industrial improvement areas the author extends the arguments to suggest how IIAs could be a progressive planning tool linking economic, property and land-use strategies. 相似文献
32.
The purpose of this paper is to examine changes in stock return variances following option introduction. The sample consists of National Market System stocks and employs both transaction returns and returns based on bid and ask quotes. Variances are decomposed into portions attributable to bid-ask spreads, return autocorrelations, and intrinsic variances. Spreads play a negligible role in explaining variance changes. A generally positive component to short-term autocorrelations falls following option introduction, increasing variances over short holding periods. Intrinsic variances fall prior to the October 1987 crash, but do not change after the crash with option introduction. 相似文献
33.
David T. Meth Ryoko Toyama Junichiro Miyabe 《Journal of Product Innovation Management》1997,14(5):323-336
The personal computer (PC) marketplace in the US presents a dizzying array of component suppliers and products. No single firm dominates the industry with a complete package of hardware and software components. Although one company's operating systems and general-purpose applications are installed on most PCs in the US, the other system components—processors, memory, storage devices, display adapters, monitors, specialized applications, and so on—come from any number of sources. David T. Methe, Ryoko Toyama, and Junichiro Miyabe point out that the PC industry in Japan also exhibits this decentralized nature. However, they also note that despite the decentralized network structure of the Japanese PC industry, one company—NEC—was able to achieve a dominant market share. To provide insight into the key issues involved in the management of complex technology, they contrast NEC's strategic approach to product development and organizational learning with the approaches taken by Fujitsu—the firm that placed a distant second in this market. Despite matching NEC in terms of technological capabilities, financial resources, and managerial talent, Fujitsu never managed to threaten NEC's dominance of the PC market in Japan. Fujitsu continually emphasized technological leadership, even at the expense of protecting its installed base. Poor coordination of resources and product development efforts resulted in incompatibilities among Fujitsu's various products, and the company failed to foster close relationships with suppliers of such key technologies as software and peripherals. NEC's PCs did not enjoy the advantages of first-to-market status or technological leadership. Instead, NEC achieved market dominance by finding the combination of product technologies that met the needs of the greatest number of consumers. Throughout almost 20 years of competition in the PC industry, NEC successfully maintained consistency and backward compatibility across its product lines. NEC also recognized the importance of third-party software developers, and carefully cultivated relations with these firms as a source of competitive advantage. In other words, NEC struck the right balance between three key factors: technological innovation, motivation of third-party developers of software and peripherals, and service to its installed base of customers. 相似文献
34.
Peter F. Pope David A. Peel 《Journal of Business Finance & Accounting》1997,24(9&10):1433-1435
In this comment we identify the key features of the Frantz and Walker (1997) game theoretic model that drive the non-disclosure equilibrium result in their paper. We argue that, although technically correct, their model fails to capture certain aspects of real-world wage bargaining that will be important in determining optimal disclosure strategies in practice. However, Frantz and Walker's paper illustrates the potential of analytical techniques to contribute to the employee disclosure debate. 相似文献
35.
36.
Harold Alderman Jere R. Behrman David R. Ross Richard Sabot 《Oxford bulletin of economics and statistics》1996,58(1):29-55
This paper estimates the private returns to human capital in Pakistani rural labour markets. The rich data used permit inclusion of several dimensions of human capital and control for endogeneity resulting from investment in human capital. The results suggest that, without data on determinants of human capital, it would not be possible to disentangle the separate effect of each dimension of human capital on wage differentials nor to distinguish human capital explanations for wage differentials from signalling and credentialist models. With control for endogeneity of human capital and selectivity into wage employment, cognitive achievement, but not schooling attainment separate from cognitive achievement nor long-run health status, affects wage differentials. 相似文献
37.
38.
David B. Humphrey 《Journal of Productivity Analysis》1993,4(1-2):9-34
Banks were substantially deregulated during the 1980s. This altered the cost-minimizing mix between deposit interest payments and operating expenses (capital and labor for branch convenience and free deposit services). Measured bank output was relatively unaffected by these changes. The proportion of deposits receiving higher interest rates increased more rapidly than factor quantities were reduced, so unit deposit costs rose. Consumers benefited, but the measured net effects for banks were negative, averaging –0.8% to –1.4% a year in net technical change from 1977 to 1988. These influences were measured three different ways and for both equilibrium and disequilibrium factor input specifications. All three approaches—a standard time trend, a time-specific index, and shifts in cross-sectional cost functions—gave consistent results. The results were robust whether measured at the banking firm or branch office level or on the cost frontier. 相似文献
39.
40.
Of the many activitiesof the Antitrust Division of theU.S. Department of Justice, we havesummarized some that raise interestingeconomic issues. We describe recentimprovements in the methodology to beused in ``coordinated effects' analysisof mergers. We also discuss four casesbrought by the DOJ that raise issues ofmarket definition, the influence ofcommon partial ownership of competitors,and the effects of fringe suppliers inconstraining collusion by large firms. 相似文献