全文获取类型
收费全文 | 25258篇 |
免费 | 155篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 5166篇 |
工业经济 | 2062篇 |
计划管理 | 4460篇 |
经济学 | 5153篇 |
综合类 | 237篇 |
运输经济 | 236篇 |
旅游经济 | 419篇 |
贸易经济 | 3982篇 |
农业经济 | 1145篇 |
经济概况 | 2536篇 |
信息产业经济 | 2篇 |
邮电经济 | 15篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 143篇 |
2021年 | 180篇 |
2020年 | 381篇 |
2019年 | 513篇 |
2018年 | 566篇 |
2017年 | 571篇 |
2016年 | 557篇 |
2015年 | 413篇 |
2014年 | 616篇 |
2013年 | 2735篇 |
2012年 | 724篇 |
2011年 | 855篇 |
2010年 | 754篇 |
2009年 | 856篇 |
2008年 | 806篇 |
2007年 | 704篇 |
2006年 | 672篇 |
2005年 | 573篇 |
2004年 | 568篇 |
2003年 | 579篇 |
2002年 | 560篇 |
2001年 | 520篇 |
2000年 | 542篇 |
1999年 | 524篇 |
1998年 | 505篇 |
1997年 | 480篇 |
1996年 | 402篇 |
1995年 | 411篇 |
1994年 | 401篇 |
1993年 | 403篇 |
1992年 | 417篇 |
1991年 | 403篇 |
1990年 | 320篇 |
1989年 | 292篇 |
1988年 | 267篇 |
1987年 | 271篇 |
1986年 | 250篇 |
1985年 | 372篇 |
1984年 | 402篇 |
1983年 | 382篇 |
1982年 | 337篇 |
1981年 | 290篇 |
1980年 | 275篇 |
1979年 | 253篇 |
1978年 | 227篇 |
1977年 | 207篇 |
1976年 | 198篇 |
1975年 | 177篇 |
1974年 | 159篇 |
1973年 | 153篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
41.
David T. Meth Ryoko Toyama Junichiro Miyabe 《Journal of Product Innovation Management》1997,14(5):323-336
The personal computer (PC) marketplace in the US presents a dizzying array of component suppliers and products. No single firm dominates the industry with a complete package of hardware and software components. Although one company's operating systems and general-purpose applications are installed on most PCs in the US, the other system components—processors, memory, storage devices, display adapters, monitors, specialized applications, and so on—come from any number of sources. David T. Methe, Ryoko Toyama, and Junichiro Miyabe point out that the PC industry in Japan also exhibits this decentralized nature. However, they also note that despite the decentralized network structure of the Japanese PC industry, one company—NEC—was able to achieve a dominant market share. To provide insight into the key issues involved in the management of complex technology, they contrast NEC's strategic approach to product development and organizational learning with the approaches taken by Fujitsu—the firm that placed a distant second in this market. Despite matching NEC in terms of technological capabilities, financial resources, and managerial talent, Fujitsu never managed to threaten NEC's dominance of the PC market in Japan. Fujitsu continually emphasized technological leadership, even at the expense of protecting its installed base. Poor coordination of resources and product development efforts resulted in incompatibilities among Fujitsu's various products, and the company failed to foster close relationships with suppliers of such key technologies as software and peripherals. NEC's PCs did not enjoy the advantages of first-to-market status or technological leadership. Instead, NEC achieved market dominance by finding the combination of product technologies that met the needs of the greatest number of consumers. Throughout almost 20 years of competition in the PC industry, NEC successfully maintained consistency and backward compatibility across its product lines. NEC also recognized the importance of third-party software developers, and carefully cultivated relations with these firms as a source of competitive advantage. In other words, NEC struck the right balance between three key factors: technological innovation, motivation of third-party developers of software and peripherals, and service to its installed base of customers. 相似文献
42.
Peter F. Pope David A. Peel 《Journal of Business Finance & Accounting》1997,24(9&10):1433-1435
In this comment we identify the key features of the Frantz and Walker (1997) game theoretic model that drive the non-disclosure equilibrium result in their paper. We argue that, although technically correct, their model fails to capture certain aspects of real-world wage bargaining that will be important in determining optimal disclosure strategies in practice. However, Frantz and Walker's paper illustrates the potential of analytical techniques to contribute to the employee disclosure debate. 相似文献
43.
44.
Harold Alderman Jere R. Behrman David R. Ross Richard Sabot 《Oxford bulletin of economics and statistics》1996,58(1):29-55
This paper estimates the private returns to human capital in Pakistani rural labour markets. The rich data used permit inclusion of several dimensions of human capital and control for endogeneity resulting from investment in human capital. The results suggest that, without data on determinants of human capital, it would not be possible to disentangle the separate effect of each dimension of human capital on wage differentials nor to distinguish human capital explanations for wage differentials from signalling and credentialist models. With control for endogeneity of human capital and selectivity into wage employment, cognitive achievement, but not schooling attainment separate from cognitive achievement nor long-run health status, affects wage differentials. 相似文献
45.
A firm employs suppliers who make specific investments. Because output demand is uncertain and the cost of enumerating contingencies high, the firm retains some unilateral control over the input quantities it purchases. To allay suppliers’ concerns over potential opportunism the firm must commit not to pit them against one another ex post by threatening to buy less from those who refuse to discount their prices. By extending most-favored treatment guarantees the firm commits not to discriminate. In some circumstances this generates efficient and opportunism-free outcomes. In others it is less effective but may remain attractive relative to other options. Evidence from field market contracts for natural gas corroborates this nondiscrimination hypothesis. 相似文献
46.
Summary. This research studies the role of multivariate distribution structures on random asset returns in determining the optimal
allocation vector for an expected utility maximizer. All our conclusions pertain for the set of risk averters. By carefully
disturbing symmetry in the distribution of the, possibly covarying, returns, we ascertain the ordinal structure of the optimized
allocation vector. Rank order of allocations is also established when a permutation symmetric random vector is mapped into
the returns vector through location and scale shifts. It is shown that increased dispersion in the vectors of location and
scale parameters benefit, ex-ante, investors as does a decrease in the rank correlation coefficient between the location and
scale parameter vectors. Revealed preference comparative static results are identified for the location and scale vectors
of asset returns. For most issues addressed, we arrive at much stronger inferences when a safe asset is available.
Received: August 8, 2000; revised version: January 8, 2001 相似文献
47.
An algebraic theory of portfolio allocation 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Summary. Using group and majorization theory, we explore what can be established about allocation of funds among assets when asymmetries
in the returns vector are carefully controlled. The key insight is that preferences over allocations can be partially ordered
via majorized convex hulls that have been generated by a permutation group. Group transitivity suffices to ensure complete
portfolio diversification. Point-wise stabilizer subgroups admit sectoral separability in fund allocations. We also bound
the admissible allocation vector by a set of linear constraints the coefficients of which are determined by group operations
on location and scale asymmetries in the rate of returns vector. For a distribution that is symmetric under a reflection group,
the linear constraints may be further strengthened whenever there exists an hyperplane that separates convex sets.
Received: May 15, 2001; revised version: March 20, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" Journal paper No. J-19797 of the Iowa Agriculture and Home Economics Experiment Station, Ames, Iowa. Project No. 3463,
and supported by Hatch Act and State of Iowa funds.
Correspondence to: D. A. Hennessy 相似文献
48.
49.
We study empirically the macroeconomic effects of an explicit de jure quantitative goal for monetary policy. Quantitative goals take three forms: exchange rates, money growth rates, and inflation targets. We analyze the effects on inflation of both having a quantitative target and hitting a declared target. Our empirical work uses an annual data set covering 42 countries between 1960 and 2000, and takes account of other determinants of inflation (such as fiscal policy, the business cycle, and openness to international trade) and the endogeneity of the monetary policy regime. We find that both having and hitting quantitative targets for monetary policy is systematically and robustly associated with lower inflation. The exact form of the monetary target matters somewhat (especially for the sustainability of the monetary regime) but is less important than having some quantitative target. Successfully achieving a quantitative monetary goal is also associated with less volatile output. 相似文献
50.
It is well known that sunspot equilibria may arise under an interest rate operating procedure in which the central bank varies the nominal rate with movements in future inflation (a forward-looking Taylor rule). This paper demonstrates that these sunspot equilibria may be learnable in the sense of E-stability. 相似文献