首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   217篇
  免费   10篇
财政金融   48篇
工业经济   13篇
计划管理   37篇
经济学   30篇
综合类   4篇
运输经济   4篇
旅游经济   14篇
贸易经济   52篇
农业经济   12篇
经济概况   13篇
  2023年   2篇
  2022年   2篇
  2021年   3篇
  2020年   3篇
  2019年   10篇
  2018年   7篇
  2017年   7篇
  2016年   6篇
  2015年   4篇
  2014年   8篇
  2013年   36篇
  2012年   6篇
  2011年   9篇
  2010年   5篇
  2009年   2篇
  2008年   8篇
  2007年   3篇
  2006年   5篇
  2005年   10篇
  2004年   13篇
  2003年   10篇
  2002年   6篇
  2001年   7篇
  2000年   5篇
  1999年   4篇
  1998年   3篇
  1997年   5篇
  1996年   6篇
  1995年   3篇
  1994年   4篇
  1993年   3篇
  1992年   3篇
  1991年   2篇
  1990年   2篇
  1989年   1篇
  1988年   2篇
  1987年   1篇
  1986年   2篇
  1985年   3篇
  1983年   1篇
  1981年   1篇
  1980年   1篇
  1978年   1篇
  1975年   1篇
  1974年   1篇
排序方式: 共有227条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
51.
We apply a gender‐aware framework to examine the self‐leadership strategies men and women early stage high‐growth entrepreneurs employ as they develop innovations. Utilizing a matched‐pair sample of early stage entrepreneurs operating firms in high‐technology business incubators, our results suggest that female and male entrepreneurs have significantly different self‐goal‐setting and self‐cueing behaviors. Results also suggest male entrepreneurs who use stronger goal‐setting behaviors increase their intellectual property development to a greater extent than female founders. Further, for female entrepreneurs who use greater self‐cueing, the negative relationship realized with intellectual property development is lower than for male entrepreneurs.  相似文献   
52.
In the pre-1914 era Australia did not develop an ocean-going merchant navy. The problem is well recognised in previous studies that assumed that it was high Australian wages that made the operational cost of deep-sea vessels uncompetitive on a global scale. This article reconstructs historical shifts in the Australian market for a seagoing workforce and demonstrates there was low recruitment of Australian labour. Drawing on new sources and inspired by efficiency wage theory the article argues that it was this shortage of a domestic labour supply that constrained the development of a national deep-sea shipping industry.  相似文献   
53.
54.
55.
In the light of criticism of the performance of Australian business, this article surveys the mounting array of firm and industry evidence to assess the performance of Australian mass production manufacturers. The focus is on lower technology sectors of food and drink, packaging, rural and consumer chemicals, and building materials because these are sectors where Australian firms faced fewer constraints. The article evaluates whether the large firms that emerged in these industries demonstrated entrepreneurship by responding to opportunities, developing their technical capabilities and learning how to manage their growing businesses effectively.  相似文献   
56.
57.
Gender equality policies aim to increase women’s participation in the market economy, but they do not always recognise that market societies reproduce inequalities at micro and macro levels. At the micro level, labour markets are gendered institutions, and at the macro level, austerity policies have inherent biases and negative impacts that fall disproportionately on women.  相似文献   
58.
59.
Efforts to improve the efficiency of the hospital sector in the National Health Service (NHS) have concentrated on measuring the unit costs of service provision. Hospitals identified as having high unit costs are considered poor performers. Several indices have been constructed to measure unit costs. These produce conflicting messages: hospitals with relatively high unit costs as measured using one index may have low unit costs according to another index. Furthermore, the publication of cost information may lead to unintended consequences and perverse behaviour, rather than genuine performance improvements. To get a more accurate picture of performance, cost information should be included within a broader performance assessment framework for hospitals.  相似文献   
60.
Over the last few years, Canadian provinces have come to see watershed-based source protection as a means of improving water quality that has been subject to upstream agricultural contamination. Cost-sharing incentive programs—whereby farmers are reimbursed for some portion of out-of-pocket expenses when they voluntarily adopt Best Management Practices—have been identified as possible means of achieving the goal. This paper uses data from the first seven years of operation of Ontario's Rural Water Quality Program for the Grand River to examine the role of financial incentives in encouraging participation. Program data supplemented with Statistics Canada's Census of Agriculture data are used to estimate a Heckman two-stage model of participation rates. Program-specific cost-sharing incentive factors, along with farm income and computer usage, are important determinants in the first-stage discrete participation decision. The most significant factor in the second-stage degree of participation decision is the maximum dollar value of grant that can be obtained by the farm; however, participation response elasticities are inelastic, ranging between 0.02 and 0.25. Au cours des dernières années, les provinces canadiennes en sont venues à considérer la protection des sources d’eau à l’échelle des bassins versants comme un moyen d’améliorer la qualité de l’eau susceptible d’être contaminée par les activités agricoles en amont. Les programmes d’incitatifs à frais partagés – dans le cadre desquels une partie des dépenses que les producteurs engagent leur sont remboursées lorsqu’ils adoptent volontairement de meilleures pratiques de gestion – sont perçus comme des moyens qui pourraient permettre d’atteindre l’objectif. Dans le présent article, nous avons utilisé les données des sept premières années d’application du Rural Water Quality Program, mis en place par l’Ontario pour la protection de la rivière Grand, afin d’examiner le rôle des incitatifs financiers dans l’encouragement à la participation. Nous avons utilisé les données de ce programme ainsi que des données tirées du Recensement de l’agriculture de Statistique Canada pour analyser les taux de participation à l’aide du modèle en deux étapes de Heckman. À la première étape, les incitatifs à frais partagés spécifiques à un programme, de même que le revenu agricole et l’utilisation d’un ordinateur, sont des facteurs importants dans le choix de participer ou non. À la deuxième étape, la valeur maximale de la subvention que peut obtenir une exploitation agricole représente le facteur le plus important. Toutefois, l’élasticité des réponses de participation est inélastique, et varie de 0,02 à 0,25.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号