全文获取类型
收费全文 | 17091篇 |
免费 | 17篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2691篇 |
工业经济 | 766篇 |
计划管理 | 2647篇 |
经济学 | 3978篇 |
综合类 | 482篇 |
运输经济 | 3篇 |
旅游经济 | 3篇 |
贸易经济 | 4530篇 |
农业经济 | 18篇 |
经济概况 | 1374篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 572篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 1篇 |
2023年 | 8篇 |
2022年 | 4篇 |
2021年 | 11篇 |
2020年 | 16篇 |
2019年 | 24篇 |
2018年 | 2314篇 |
2017年 | 2070篇 |
2016年 | 1221篇 |
2015年 | 100篇 |
2014年 | 103篇 |
2013年 | 107篇 |
2012年 | 451篇 |
2011年 | 1958篇 |
2010年 | 1840篇 |
2009年 | 1541篇 |
2008年 | 1519篇 |
2007年 | 1879篇 |
2006年 | 70篇 |
2005年 | 397篇 |
2004年 | 474篇 |
2003年 | 558篇 |
2002年 | 258篇 |
2001年 | 67篇 |
2000年 | 54篇 |
1999年 | 4篇 |
1998年 | 19篇 |
1996年 | 16篇 |
1995年 | 1篇 |
1994年 | 2篇 |
1993年 | 2篇 |
1991年 | 2篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1986年 | 13篇 |
1985年 | 2篇 |
1982年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
81.
This study investigates whether and how central clearing influences the overall liquidity needs in a network of financial obligations. Utilizing the approach of flow network theory, we show that the effect of adding a central clearing counterparty (CCP) is decomposed into two effects: central routing, and central netting effects. Each effect can produce different liquidity needs according to different liquidity scenarios. The analysis indicates that adding a CCP in times of financial distress successfully reduces the overall liquidity needs if and only if the netting efficiency of the CCP is sufficiently high. Furthermore, once the economy is no longer in financial distress, higher netting efficiency of the CCP could conversely increase the overall liquidity needs. The results have implications for the effectiveness of CCPs in mitigating systemic risk in times of financial distress, and their operating costs once the distress has passed. 相似文献
82.
Petre Caraiani 《Empirica》2018,45(4):707-745
It is well known that southeast Europe is the least developed area in Europe. Using a methodology based on the idea of heterogeneous firms, this paper studies the degree to which firm heterogeneity and resource misallocation can explain the lower TFP in southeast Europe. The results show a significant degree of heterogeneity and resource misallocation, although the results are sensitive to the calibration used. There is evidence that firm-level productivity depends on firm size, while taxation negatively influences it. There is also some evidence that foreign-owned firms are more competitive, as are exporting firms. Results are generally robust across the various specifications used, but less so relative to the measure of productivity used. Additional evidence suggests that infrastructure-related obstacles as well as institutional instability drive the output distortion, while no factor is underlined as a significant driver of capital distortions, suggesting the need for better data sources for the latter. 相似文献
83.
The Baltimore Gas and Electric Company (BGE) undertook a dynamic pricing experiment to test customer price responsiveness
to different dynamic pricing options. The pilot ran during the summers of 2008 and 2009 and was called the Smart Energy Pricing (SEP) Pilot. In 2008, it tested two types of dynamic pricing tariffs: critical peak pricing (CPP) and peak time rebate (PTR) tariffs.
About a thousand customers were randomly placed on these tariffs and some of them were paired with one of two enabling technologies,
a device known as the Energy Orb and a switch for cycling central air conditioners. The usage of a randomly chosen control
group of customers was also monitored during the same time period. In 2009, BGE repeated the pilot program with the same customers
who participated in the 2008 pilot, but this time it only tested the PTR tariff. In this paper, we estimate a constant elasticity
of substitution (CES) model on the SEP pilot’s hourly consumption, pricing and weather data. We derive substitution and daily
price elasticities and predictive equations for estimating the magnitude of demand response under a variety of dynamic prices.
We also test for the persistence of impacts across the two summers. In addition, we report average peak demand reduction for
each of the treatment cells in the SEP pilot and compare the findings with those reported from earlier pilots. These results
show conclusively that it is possible to incentivize customers to reduce their peak period loads using price signals. More
importantly, these reductions do not wear off when the pricing plans are implemented over two consecutive summers. Our analyses
reveal that SEP participants reduced their peak usages in the range of 18 to 33% in the first summer of the SEP pilot and
continued these reductions in the second summer. 相似文献
84.
This paper takes up an argument from Ronald Rogowski about the “natural affinity” between trade and an electoral system with proportional representation. We draw on literature on the historical determinants of electoral system choice to advance the general argument that trade integration and PR are related because the adoption of PR helps to secure gains from trade. Our specific model of electoral rule changes in the age of globalization predicts that the likelihood of electoral rule change towards more proportionality increases with levels of trade integration in the world economy. The theoretical model draws on a micro model of the distributive effects of increased economic integration. Because more proportional systems are more credibly able to commit to compensate the losers of globalization processes, there will be increased demand to change the electoral system towards more proportionality under economic circumstances that increase the costs of maintaining a closed economy. In accordance with our model, our empirical tests find a positive association between (a) trade integration and the proportionality of the electoral system, (b) proportionality and social spending, and (c) global integration levels and the probability of electoral rules changes that render voting rules more proportional. 相似文献
85.
86.
The 1990s were tumultuous times for the US Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs) industry. Significant structural changes
occurred during the decade, especially after the 1993 Revenue Reconciliation Act, which tremendously boosted the flow of funds
into the system by allowing the participation of institutional investors in REITs. As a result, the industry experienced remarkable
asset growth during the decade, with a large number of initial public offerings and substantial increases in market capitalization.
Employing the Data Envelopment Analysis-type Malmquist index approach, this paper explores the impact of such environmental
changes on productivity growth, efficiency change, and technological progress of REITs. Our results indicate that while efficiency
of the REITs significantly increased, their average productivity declined and technology regressed during this decade. It
appears that the typical REIT has failed to improve technically, but exerted substantial effort to catch up with the best
practice ones relying mainly on aggressive growth strategies. However, our empirical results indicate that they might have
overextended themselves as most began to suffer from diseconomies of scale.
相似文献
Ihsan IsikEmail: |
87.
A nonstationary simultaneous autoregressive model \({X^{(n)}_k=\alpha \Big(X^{(n)}_{k-1}+X^{(n)}_{k+1}\Big)+\varepsilon_k, k=1, 2, \ldots , n-1}\), is investigated, where \({X^{(n)}_0}\) and \({X^{(n)}_n}\) are given random variables. It is shown that in the unstable case α = 1/2 the least squares estimator of the autoregressive parameter converges to a functional of a standard Wiener process with a rate of convergence n 2, while in the stable situation |α| < 1/2 the estimator is biased but asymptotically normal with a rate n 1/2. 相似文献
88.
A play-the-winner-type urn design with reduced variability 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Anastasia Ivanova 《Metrika》2003,58(1):1-13
We propose a new adaptive allocation rule, the drop-the-loser, that randomizes subjects in the course of a trial comparing
treatments with dichotomous outcomes. The rule tends to assign more patients to better treatments with the same limiting proportion
as the randomized play-the-winner rule. The new design has significantly less variable allocation proportion than the randomized
play-the-winner rule. Decrease in variability translates into a gain in statistical power. For some values of success probabilities
the drop-the-loser rule has a double advantage over conventional equal allocation in that it has better power and assigns
more subjects to the better treatment.
Acknowledgments. I thank Stephen Durham, the associate editor, and the referees for their helpful suggestions. 相似文献
89.
90.
Louis Kaplow 《International Tax and Public Finance》2010,17(1):25-42
The marginal social value of income redistribution is understood to depend on both the concavity of individuals’ utility functions
and the concavity of the social welfare function. In the pertinent literatures, notably on optimal income taxation and on
normative inequality measurement, it seems to be accepted that the role of these two sources of concavity is symmetric with
regard to the social concern about inequality in the distribution of income. Direct examination of the question, however,
reveals that this is not the case. Concavity of utility has a simple, direct effect on the marginal social value of redistribution,
as might be expected, whereas concavity of the social welfare function has a more subtle influence, one that in some cases
may not be very significant. The implications of this difference are examined for some standard forms of utility and welfare
functions, including particular versions that appear in the optimal income taxation literature. 相似文献