首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   171篇
  免费   12篇
财政金融   15篇
工业经济   12篇
计划管理   38篇
经济学   27篇
综合类   2篇
运输经济   1篇
旅游经济   8篇
贸易经济   29篇
农业经济   40篇
经济概况   11篇
  2023年   1篇
  2022年   1篇
  2020年   1篇
  2019年   6篇
  2018年   3篇
  2017年   6篇
  2016年   7篇
  2015年   5篇
  2014年   7篇
  2013年   14篇
  2012年   8篇
  2011年   5篇
  2010年   8篇
  2009年   3篇
  2008年   8篇
  2007年   5篇
  2006年   5篇
  2005年   11篇
  2004年   5篇
  2003年   7篇
  2002年   3篇
  2001年   4篇
  2000年   5篇
  1998年   3篇
  1997年   3篇
  1996年   2篇
  1995年   3篇
  1994年   6篇
  1993年   4篇
  1992年   3篇
  1991年   2篇
  1990年   6篇
  1989年   6篇
  1988年   3篇
  1987年   2篇
  1985年   1篇
  1984年   1篇
  1983年   1篇
  1978年   1篇
  1977年   3篇
  1975年   2篇
  1969年   1篇
  1968年   1篇
  1952年   1篇
排序方式: 共有183条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
161.
162.
163.
The term relationship marketing has been used to describe a wide range of marketing tactics. In this article, three dimensions that may be used to categorize these tactics are identified: personalization, individualization, and continuity. Research is presented demonstrating that the effectiveness of each type of tactic is influenced by buyer involvement in the product category, although the nature of this influence differs by country and gender. This suggests that managers contemplating relationship marketing programs should consider buyer involvement levels, and that researchers studying relationship marketing effectiveness should control for this variable. © 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.  相似文献   
164.
A model of the development of naïve theories of price is presented and tested. The criterion used to account for price variations within a product category is product features at age five, product features and quality at age ten, product quality and buyer utility at age thirteen, and a combination of supply considerations and buyer utility/demand in adulthood. Five-year-olds do not justify their use of product features as a price criterion; however, older respondents all justify their price criterion by referring to a source of value. At age ten, variation in the amount of manufacturing inputs is the source of value which justifies the use of product features as a price criterion; at age thirteen, variations in the quality of manufacturing inputs justify the use of product quality as a price criterion; and in adulthood, relative scarcity and buyer preferences justify the use of cost and demand as price criteria.  相似文献   
165.
The purpose of this paper is to assess the contribution of each one of the major factors explaining Australian nominal GDP growth: technological change, movements in the terms of trade, increases in the endowments of labour and capital, and changes in domestic output prices. We use an index number technique as well as an econometric approach. Moreover, we look at several methods to decompose total factor productivity growth into secular and unexpected components. All our empirical results have a tight theoretical foundation, being based on the GDP function approach to modelling the production sector of an open economy.  相似文献   
166.
In previous issues leading public figures have indicated the desirable con tent of British economic policy. Roger Fox, an economist, and Kenneth Judge, a sociologist, who advise the SDP, argue, first, that more me should be made of the market, even where it disturbs established interests, and, secondly, that private financing should be used for social services.  相似文献   
167.
168.
We note that calibration parameters in a multi‐country Armington trade model play a role similar to that of econometric residuals: they allow the model to fit the data exactly. We use this premise to evaluate the “fit” of a standard multi‐country computable general‐equilibrium model. We find that the model relies heavily on these parameters to explain the pattern of trade. In 33 of the 46 commodity groups we assess, modeled economic behavior explains less than 20% of the variation in bilateral trade. In a calibration‐ as‐estimation experiment, we estimate the commodity‐specific elasticities of substitution consistent with a well‐fitting model and find that they are substantially higher than widely accepted estimates.  相似文献   
169.
In recent years, the assessment of intangible benefits has become an explicit requirement of investment evaluation techniques. By contrast, assessments of three factors which can prevent the realization of any benefits have not become an explicit requirement. Those three factors are disbenefits, reliability and utilization. The importance of these factors may sometimes be identified prior to investment evaluation when exploratory methods such as contingency planning are used. However, evidence presented in this paper suggests that these three factors are often overlooked. Further, the evidence presented in this paper suggests that investment performance often suffers as a result. Accordingly, it is argued that investment evaluations need to be balanced by making assessments of disbenefits, reliability and utilization an explicit requirement. This argument is supported by reporting of experiences from action research. These experiences indicate that investment evaluations can be balanced by making assessments of disbenefits, reliability and utilization an explicit requirement.  相似文献   
170.
When retailers conduct product assortment planning (PAP), they determine (1) The variety of merchandise, (2) The depth of merchandise, and (3) Service level or the amount of inventory to allocate to each stock-keeping unit (SKU). Despite longstanding recognition of its importance, no dominant PAP solution exists, and theoretical and decision support models address only some of the factors that complicate assortment planning. This article simultaneously addresses the variety, depth, and service level aspects of PAP to provide a more thorough understanding. A review of current academic literature and best trade practices identifies open questions and directions for further research and applications.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号