全文获取类型
收费全文 | 16952篇 |
免费 | 2篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2672篇 |
工业经济 | 756篇 |
计划管理 | 2583篇 |
经济学 | 3929篇 |
综合类 | 482篇 |
运输经济 | 1篇 |
旅游经济 | 3篇 |
贸易经济 | 4534篇 |
经济概况 | 1372篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 578篇 |
出版年
2022年 | 3篇 |
2021年 | 3篇 |
2020年 | 2篇 |
2019年 | 5篇 |
2018年 | 2303篇 |
2017年 | 2059篇 |
2016年 | 1210篇 |
2015年 | 96篇 |
2014年 | 92篇 |
2013年 | 71篇 |
2012年 | 445篇 |
2011年 | 1948篇 |
2010年 | 1831篇 |
2009年 | 1518篇 |
2008年 | 1517篇 |
2007年 | 1872篇 |
2006年 | 74篇 |
2005年 | 393篇 |
2004年 | 466篇 |
2003年 | 552篇 |
2002年 | 256篇 |
2001年 | 67篇 |
2000年 | 51篇 |
1999年 | 2篇 |
1998年 | 20篇 |
1997年 | 2篇 |
1996年 | 15篇 |
1995年 | 6篇 |
1994年 | 4篇 |
1993年 | 6篇 |
1992年 | 2篇 |
1991年 | 2篇 |
1989年 | 2篇 |
1987年 | 5篇 |
1986年 | 15篇 |
1985年 | 4篇 |
1984年 | 4篇 |
1983年 | 2篇 |
1980年 | 3篇 |
1979年 | 3篇 |
1977年 | 3篇 |
1972年 | 2篇 |
1969年 | 1篇 |
1967年 | 2篇 |
1963年 | 1篇 |
1948年 | 1篇 |
1937年 | 1篇 |
1934年 | 1篇 |
1933年 | 1篇 |
1930年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
241.
242.
Xiang Bi 《Journal of Regulatory Economics》2017,51(1):18-40
Environmental policies in the United States have primarily taken the form of media-specific regulations that emphasize end-of-pipe pollution control. This can lead to the shifting of pollution across environmental media, thereby having the potential to solve one environmental problem by creating a new problem. This study uses data from 228 coal-fired power plants that report to the Toxics Release Inventory to conduct an empirical examination of the extent to which media-specific regulation has caused power plants to shift their toxic air releases to waterways, land, or transfers for offsite recycling facilities. Controlling for plant-level fixed effects, scale of production, and environmental inspections and enforcement under air regulation, this study finds that adopting tougher air pollution regulation that designates counties as being in nonattainment status with the National Ambient Air Quality Standards significantly increased toxic releases to waterways and land. 相似文献
243.
Nuno Garoupa 《International Review of Economics》2012,59(2):223-229
Ronald Coase himself never wrote about law and economics in Europe. Yet many of his insights about the development of the
discipline in the United States are extremely useful to our understanding of the methodological and practical challenges faced
by European law and economics (as in most civil law jurisdictions). This paper argues that a careful consideration of Coase’s
insights might address some of the current limitations. 相似文献
244.
We show how to obtain coherent structural-form (SF) exclusion restrictions using the reduced-form (RF) parameter ratios. It will be shown that an over-identified SF corresponds to a group of regressors sharing the same RF ratio value; those regressors should be excluded jointly from the SF. If there is no group structure, then the SF is just-identified;
in this case, however, it is no longer clear which regressor should be excluded. Hence, just-identified SF’s are more arbitrary than over-identified SF’s in terms of exclusion restrictions. This is in stark contrast to the notion that the former is less arbitrary than the latter,
because the former excludes fewer regressors. We formalize these points, and then suggest to find the number of modes in the
estimated RF ratios as a way to find groups in the ratios. For this purpose, an informal graphical method using a kernel nonparametric
method and a formal modality test are employed. An empirical example with selling price in a residential real estate market
and duration on the market as two endogenous variables is provided.
The authors are grateful to the editor and two anonymous referees for their comments 相似文献
245.
Should we give equal weight to all responses in a choice experiment? Previous Choice Modelling papers have considered the issue of the internal consistency of choices—such as the extent to which strictly-dominated options are chosen. In this paper, a different focus is employed, namely the extent to which people choose options which violate their stated upper or lower limits for the acceptable levels for individual attributes. Since hypothetical over-statement of WTP has been a focus in stated preference studies, we concentrate on violations of stated upper limits of WTP, and explore the effects of “editing” such choices using a variable censoring rule and alternative approaches to re-classifying choices. The empirical case study is a choice experiment on eco-tourists in Rwanda. Our main conclusion is that the suggested approach offers a useful way of imposing consistency on choices, and that editing choices in this manner has an appreciable impact on estimated willingness to pay. However, issues remain with regard to explaining why people apparently violate their stated maximum willingness to pay. 相似文献
246.
The Borda rule,Condorcet consistency and Condorcet stability 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Summary. The Borda rule is known to be the least vulnerable scoring rule to Condorcet inconsistency, Saari (2000). Such inconsistency
occurs when the Condorcet winner (the alternative which is preferred to any other alternative by a simple majority) is not
selected by the Borda rule. This note exposes the relationship between the Borda rule and the Condorcet q-majority principle as well as the Condorcet q-majority voting rule. The main result establishes that the Borda rule is Condorcet q-majority consistent when where k is the number of alternatives. The second result establishes that is the minimal degree of majority decisiveness corresponding to the Borda rule under sincere voting. The same majority is
required to ensure decisiveness under the Borda rule and to ensure that a q-rule (the generalized q-majority Condorcet rule) is a voting rule.
Received: April 8, 2002; revised version: July 17, 2002
Correspondence to:S. Nitzan 相似文献
247.
We examine the properties of a two-country dynamic Heckscher–Ohlin model that allows for preferences to be non-homothetic.
We show that the model has a continuum of steady state equilibria under free trade, with the initial conditions determining
which equilibrium will be attained. We establish conditions under which a static Heckscher–Ohlin theorem will hold in the
steady state, and also conditions for a dynamic Heckscher–Ohlin theorem to hold. If both goods are normal, each country will
have a unique autarkic steady state, and all steady state equilibria are saddle points. We also consider the case in which
one good is inferior, and show that this can lead to multiple autarkic steady states, violations of the static Heckscher–Ohlin
theorem in the steady state. Furthermore, there may exist steady state equilibria that Pareto dominate other steady states.
These steady states will be unstable if discount factors are the same in each country, although they may exhibit dynamic indeterminacy
if discount factors differ. 相似文献
248.
Johan Willner 《Empirica》2008,35(5):449-464
This contribution analyses a market with an upstream bottleneck monopoly and a downstream activity that may either be vertically
integrated or separated. Separation always reduces the consumer surplus, and the total surplus unless there are large cost
reductions. Downstream competition from a public or private network monopoly would crowd out other firms, also when public
ownership is associated with more modest objectives than welfare-maximisation. A market is therefore less likely to remain
a mixed oligopoly than without vertical relations. However, private firms would survive in a moderately welfare-improving
mixed oligopoly with cross-subsidisation and access charges equal to marginal costs.
相似文献
Johan WillnerEmail: |
249.
Ross Baldick 《Journal of Regulatory Economics》2018,54(2):165-194
Coincident peak pricing is used in several electricity markets to recover the embedded cost of infrastructure, such as transmission. In this approach, measured consumption at the time of the peak is used to set charges for that pricing period or a subsequent period. If transmission costs are truly sunk, then such a recovery is unlikely to be efficient. However, in the context of growing peak demand, new additions must be built. We consider the incentive properties of coincident peak pricing when related investments are not considered to be sunk, finding that it can reproduce the incentive properties of an ideal time-varying price. We also consider several variations on this assumption. 相似文献
250.
Jeremy De Valck Steven Broekx Inge Liekens Joris Aertsens Liesbet Vranken 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2017,66(1):17-43
This paper investigates the effect of nearby nature substitute sites on preferences for nature restoration. Contrary to prior studies, we use a respondent-centric approach to control for substitute sites. We assess each respondent-specific spatial context by computing densities of nature substitute sites within various ranges from each respondent’s home. This approach considers the use and non-use values of nature together. Data from three similar discrete choice experiments carried out in Flanders (Belgium) are compared. Different spatial discounting factors are tested to explore how the substitution effect behaves with regard to distance. Latent class analyses are performed to account for preference heterogeneity among respondents. We observe divergent behaviours across groups of respondents. The “distance-to-substitutes” affects how respondents gauge substitute sites. We find a significant influence of the squared average buffer distance but this effect varies in sign across case studies and classes of respondents. Our results demonstrate that individual-specific GIS data can significantly improve the representation of the spatial context and the transferability of value functions. However, the roles played by preference heterogeneity and nature perception on respondents’ capacity to value nature still deserves further attention in future research. 相似文献