全文获取类型
收费全文 | 13901篇 |
免费 | 576篇 |
国内免费 | 16篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 1842篇 |
工业经济 | 842篇 |
计划管理 | 3049篇 |
经济学 | 2518篇 |
综合类 | 943篇 |
运输经济 | 209篇 |
旅游经济 | 103篇 |
贸易经济 | 2104篇 |
农业经济 | 829篇 |
经济概况 | 2031篇 |
邮电经济 | 23篇 |
出版年
2025年 | 13篇 |
2024年 | 49篇 |
2023年 | 65篇 |
2022年 | 201篇 |
2021年 | 376篇 |
2020年 | 477篇 |
2019年 | 700篇 |
2018年 | 336篇 |
2017年 | 557篇 |
2016年 | 568篇 |
2015年 | 672篇 |
2014年 | 754篇 |
2013年 | 989篇 |
2012年 | 1063篇 |
2011年 | 1339篇 |
2010年 | 1170篇 |
2009年 | 847篇 |
2008年 | 851篇 |
2007年 | 766篇 |
2006年 | 759篇 |
2005年 | 695篇 |
2004年 | 276篇 |
2003年 | 227篇 |
2002年 | 228篇 |
2001年 | 207篇 |
2000年 | 147篇 |
1999年 | 57篇 |
1998年 | 18篇 |
1997年 | 18篇 |
1996年 | 9篇 |
1995年 | 7篇 |
1994年 | 7篇 |
1993年 | 8篇 |
1992年 | 4篇 |
1991年 | 5篇 |
1990年 | 4篇 |
1989年 | 4篇 |
1988年 | 6篇 |
1987年 | 8篇 |
1984年 | 4篇 |
1981年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
81.
地区宗教传统与民营企业创始资金来源 总被引:1,自引:1,他引:1
因为新创弱性和合法性不足,民营企业创立时的资金来源在很大程度上要依赖于资金提供者之间的相互信任或情感联结。相比于成熟企业,创业企业很难获取正式制度和资本市场的支持,从而非正式的制度、文化、传统在创业企业创立和成长过程中显得尤为重要。本文以"第九次私营企业调查"问卷数据为基础,考察宗教信仰与企业创始资金来源之间的关系。研究结果表明,地区宗教传统越浓厚,民营企业创始资金来源构成中来自创业者个人的出资比例越低,来自家族外部成员的出资比例越高;而有宗教信仰的创业者则会吸引来自家族成员的更多出资,同时其个人的出资比例会有所降低。因此,宗教传统在一定程度上影响着社会整体信任水平,创业者的宗教信仰影响着对创业者个人信任水平及其与家族的情感联结,这可以部分缓解创业企业获取创始资金时的信息和代理问题。 相似文献
82.
GUANG‐ZHEN SUN 《Journal of Public Economic Theory》2012,14(6):911-925
When does everyone genuinely contribute in the private provision of a local public good? We first introduce a monotonic condition to characterize the relationship between the structure of the network that underlie the noncooperative game of private provision of local public goods on the one hand, and the preferences of the agents on the other, showing that the monotonic condition is a sufficient and necessary condition of existence of a distributed Nash equilibrium (DNE) in which each agent exerts a positive amount of effort to provision of the public good (Theorem 1). We then study the number of equilibria, and, by using the monotonic condition, characterize the condition under which the DNE set is a singleton, a continuum, or null (Theorem 2). As it turns out, the structure of the network and the agents’ preferences jointly shape the effort profile in the provision of local public goods. 相似文献
83.
84.
以利用wos数据库检索到的、发表于1997—2013年期间的、关于跨国并购的643篇英文文献为数据源,利用动态网络分析软件Citespace,通过作者共引分析确定了企业跨国并购研究领域中的知名学者,通过文献共引分析确定了企业跨国并购研究的理论基础,并分析理论发展规律。进一步分析得到目前跨国并购研究领域的高频主题词,包括文化、银行跨国并购、汽车产业、进入方式、战略联盟、法律、知识转移、贸易保护、中国企业、中国、学习能力、国家文化等。最后,结合实际,为跨国并购研究的进一步开展提供了参考建议。 相似文献
85.
Health insurance reform in Massachusetts lowered the cost of both pregnancy (by increased coverage of pregnancy‐related medical events) and pregnancy prevention (by increasing access to reliable contraception). We empirically examine fertility responses and find no overall effect from increased coverage due to the Massachusetts reform. This finding, however, masks substantial heterogeneity. For married women aged 20 to 34—with high latent fertility and pregnancy wantedness—fertility increased by approximately 1%. For unmarried women in the same age range—for whom pregnancies are typically unwanted—fertility declined by 8%. (JEL I13, I18, J13) 相似文献
86.
Marc Fleurbaey Marie‐Louise Leroux Pierre Pestieau Gregory Ponthiere 《International Economic Review》2016,57(1):177-210
A premature death unexpectedly brings a life and a career to their end, leading to substantial welfare losses. We study the retirement decision in an economy with risky lifetime and compare the laissez‐faire with egalitarian social optima. We consider two social objectives: (1) the maximin on expected lifetime welfare, allowing for a compensation for unequal life expectancies, and (2) the maximin on realized lifetime welfare, allowing for a compensation for unequal lifetimes. The latter optimum involves, in general, decreasing lifetime consumption profiles as well as raising the retirement age. This result is robust to the introduction of unequal life expectancies and unequal productivities. 相似文献
87.
开发乡村生态旅游探析 总被引:16,自引:1,他引:16
本文在分析乡村景观的特点和乡村生态旅游开发的意义基础上,提出了乡村生态旅游的基本类型,初步探讨了开发乡村生态旅游应注意的问题及对策。 相似文献
88.
This paper shows that, in the 2 × 3 sector‐specific capital Harris–Todaro model, capital growth owing to either domestic or foreign investment always enhances the welfare of the country (i.e. non‐immiserizing), and this result of non‐immiserizing foreign investment holds regardless of initial holdings of foreign capital; the policy of industrial targeting via capital investment is more effective vis‐à‐vis the (neoclassical) 2 × 2 mobile‐capital Harris–Todaro model or the Heckscher–Ohlin model; in contrast to the recent generalization by Marjit and Beladi (2003 ), capital growth cannot be immiserizing in the present model, even if it destroys the “envelope theorem.” 相似文献
89.
In this article we study a very simple trial and error learning process in the context of a Cournot oligopoly. Without any knowledge of the payoff functions players increase, respectively decrease, their quantity as long as this leads to higher profits. We show that despite the absence of any coordination or punishing device this process converges to the joint‐profit‐maximizing outcome. 相似文献
90.
We start with the premise that if policy discounting is to have any welfare relevance, one has to accept it being a derivative of a social welfare function (SWF). We show that if that derivative is to have a net present value (NPV) form, then the baseline allocation must be stationary. In addition, we show that at a stationary baseline in an overlapping generations growth economy, the intergenerationally fair discount rate equals the growth rate of per‐capita consumption, which is, roughly, 2% for the United States. This differs from the interest rate, even in the golden rule equilibrium, unless population growth is null. The last result is based on the main theorem in Mertens and Rubinchik (2012) and is demonstrated for a policy space that might naturally arise in applications. 相似文献