全文获取类型
收费全文 | 1396篇 |
免费 | 31篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 178篇 |
工业经济 | 98篇 |
计划管理 | 298篇 |
经济学 | 306篇 |
综合类 | 4篇 |
运输经济 | 9篇 |
旅游经济 | 6篇 |
贸易经济 | 308篇 |
农业经济 | 51篇 |
经济概况 | 130篇 |
邮电经济 | 39篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 11篇 |
2020年 | 19篇 |
2019年 | 22篇 |
2018年 | 26篇 |
2017年 | 23篇 |
2016年 | 31篇 |
2015年 | 12篇 |
2014年 | 41篇 |
2013年 | 169篇 |
2012年 | 45篇 |
2011年 | 56篇 |
2010年 | 43篇 |
2009年 | 60篇 |
2008年 | 47篇 |
2007年 | 52篇 |
2006年 | 39篇 |
2005年 | 31篇 |
2004年 | 52篇 |
2003年 | 50篇 |
2002年 | 46篇 |
2001年 | 26篇 |
2000年 | 22篇 |
1999年 | 23篇 |
1998年 | 21篇 |
1997年 | 22篇 |
1996年 | 28篇 |
1995年 | 12篇 |
1994年 | 10篇 |
1993年 | 17篇 |
1992年 | 14篇 |
1991年 | 10篇 |
1990年 | 9篇 |
1989年 | 10篇 |
1988年 | 15篇 |
1987年 | 14篇 |
1986年 | 21篇 |
1985年 | 26篇 |
1984年 | 23篇 |
1983年 | 15篇 |
1982年 | 10篇 |
1981年 | 10篇 |
1980年 | 11篇 |
1978年 | 13篇 |
1977年 | 9篇 |
1975年 | 12篇 |
1974年 | 9篇 |
1973年 | 12篇 |
1972年 | 16篇 |
1970年 | 8篇 |
1969年 | 9篇 |
排序方式: 共有1427条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
61.
This article provides evidence that college students’ effort can be manipulated substantially by making changes in the college testing regime and moreover that student effort is a meaningful input in education production. The evidence comes from a quasi-experiment where a mid-semester test with a pass requirement is introduced to a mandatory one-semester Business School course in Macroeconomics. Four cohorts of students – one before and three after the introduction of the pass requirement – have reported their study effort twice during the semester, and the relationship between achievement and study effort is investigated by using a within-subject within-student across-study periods approach. 相似文献
62.
Hans Westlund 《Review of social economy》2013,71(2):163-182
Recent research has shown growing shares of employment in the social economy (or non-profit sector) both in the European Union and in the United States. In the EU, there seems to be growing hopes that the social economy will be capable of contributing to local progress on the unemployment issue in crisis regions. This paper analyses employment in certain entrepreneurial forms, usually considered belonging to the social economy, in Sweden during the 1990s. The results show considerable regional differences of employment in the social economy, but also that its share of the labor market is very limited. The effect of social-economic organizations on employment, therefore, is probably mainly indirect in as much as they function as platforms for cooperation between firms or else as embryos for enterprises by strengthening local entrepreneurship and helping to nurture a deposit of social capital which has visible effects on private business and jobs. However, these effects need more detailed examinations. 相似文献
63.
Hans E Jensen 《Review of social economy》2013,71(1):101-112
Sen's capability approach has a culturally specific side, with capabilities influenced by social structures and institutions. Although Sen acknowledges this, he expresses his theory in individualistic terms and makes little allowance for culture or social structure. The present paper draws from recent social theory to discuss how the capability approach could be developed to give an explicit treatment of cultural and structural matters. Capabilities depend not only on entitlements but on institutional roles and personal relations: these can be represented openly if capabilities are disaggregated into individual, social and structural capacities. The three layers interact, and a full analysis of capabilities should consider them all. A stratified method implies that raising entitlements will not on its own be enough to enhance capabilities and that cultural and structural changes will be needed. 相似文献
64.
In the present paper, we are concerned with the behavioural consequences of consumers having nontransitive preference relations. Data sets consist of finitely many observations of price vectors and consumption bundles. A preference relation rationalizes a data set provided that for every observed consumption bundle, all strictly preferred bundles are more expensive than the observed bundle. Our main result is that data sets can be rationalized by a smooth nontransitive preference relation if and only if prices can normalized such that the law of demand is satisfied. Market data sets consist of finitely many observations of price vectors, lists of individual incomes and aggregate demands. We apply our main result to characterize market data sets consistent with equilibrium behaviour of pure-exchange economies with smooth nontransitive consumers. 相似文献
65.
In this paper we consider deterministic seasonal variation in quarterly industrial production for several European countries, and we address the question whether this variation has become more similar across countries over time. Due to economic and institutional factors, one may expect convergence across business cycles. When these have similar characteristics as seasonal cycles, one may perhaps also find convergence in seasonality. To this aim, we propose a method that is based on treating the set of production series as a panel. By testing for the relevant parameter restrictions for moving window samples, we examine the hypothesis of convergence in deterministic seasonality while allowing for seasonal unit roots. Our main empirical finding is that there is no evidence for convergence in seasonality. 相似文献
66.
The evidence presented in the paper rejects the twin deficit hypothesis for the Austrian current account balance during the
last two decades. The results are based on an estimate of a vector error correction model including quarterly data for the
current account balance and potentially relevant variables driving its dynamics. We compute the variance decomposition of
the current account's forecast error and its generalized impulse responses to shocks in the innovations of the system. The
results in favor of intertemporal expenditure reallocation cannot be reproduced within a second analysis including the current
account and a measure of net output, however. The estimated implicit current account balance, interpreted as the discounted
expected change in future net output, does not follow the actual behaviour of the current account.
First version received: June 1999/Final version received: March 2001 相似文献
67.
Hans Opschoor 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2010,45(1):3-23
Curbing global warming by setting long term maxima for temperature rise or concentrations of greenhouse gases defines spaces
within which further emissions of these gases are to remain (referred to here as ‘carbon spaces’). This paper addresses questions
related to how to share between countries the carbon space and/or efforts to stay within it, in the perspective of sustainable
development; different allocation mechanisms are reviewed, responding to criteria such as ‘responsibility’ for climate change,
‘capability’ to engage in abating it, and ‘potential’ or future contribution. The carbon space remaining at any time will
depend on effective mitigation up till that time, and will condense if more stringent maxima are to be set; per capita this
space becomes smaller with rising population. Sharing the carbon space in a fair way requires “convergence” of currently widely
unequal per capita emissions. If the world is to stay within the carbon space consistent with <2° warming, then developed
economies—the wealthiest sources of greenhouse gases should quickly and deeply engage in mitigation. Also, substantial mitigation
is to take place in developing countries and that this will require substantial support to developing countries (financially,
technologically). Changing development paths can make a major contribution to climate change mitigation; this requires changes
in investment, production and consumption patterns. Green New Deals as proposed in the context of a widened response to the
current economic crisis could become a first phase of a fundamental transition towards a decarbonised global economy worldwide.
Concerns to do with equity as well as sustainability must be incorporated and integrated into coherent transitory strategies. 相似文献
68.
Hans Andersson Sailesh Ramamurtie Bharat Ramaswami 《Journal of economic behavior & organization》2003,50(4):477-493
In the developed countries, a majority of farm households receive at least as much income from nonfarm sources as from the farm. Such part-time farms have survived inspite of lower returns than full-time farms. This paper considers when lower returns to part-time farming could be compensated by risk-reduction due to diversification of income sources. The paper uses a dynamic portfolio choice model with labor income. The model and results could be applied in other contexts as well. 相似文献
69.
70.