首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   389篇
  免费   0篇
财政金融   67篇
工业经济   13篇
计划管理   52篇
经济学   78篇
综合类   3篇
运输经济   3篇
旅游经济   4篇
贸易经济   86篇
农业经济   3篇
经济概况   29篇
邮电经济   51篇
  2024年   2篇
  2023年   3篇
  2021年   2篇
  2020年   4篇
  2019年   9篇
  2018年   3篇
  2017年   8篇
  2016年   10篇
  2015年   7篇
  2014年   17篇
  2013年   56篇
  2012年   11篇
  2011年   10篇
  2010年   14篇
  2009年   15篇
  2008年   18篇
  2007年   31篇
  2006年   17篇
  2005年   24篇
  2004年   3篇
  2003年   3篇
  2002年   6篇
  2001年   9篇
  2000年   6篇
  1999年   4篇
  1998年   6篇
  1997年   3篇
  1996年   7篇
  1995年   7篇
  1994年   3篇
  1993年   8篇
  1992年   3篇
  1991年   4篇
  1990年   3篇
  1989年   4篇
  1987年   2篇
  1986年   2篇
  1985年   3篇
  1984年   3篇
  1982年   2篇
  1979年   2篇
  1974年   3篇
  1973年   2篇
  1972年   8篇
  1971年   4篇
  1970年   2篇
  1969年   3篇
  1966年   1篇
  1963年   2篇
  1961年   2篇
排序方式: 共有389条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
21.
The question of whether alcohol and tobacco are consumed as complements or substitutes is crucial for determining the side-effects of anti-smoking policies. Numerous papers have empirically addressed this issue by estimating demand systems for alcohol and tobacco, and subsequently calculating cross-price effects. However, this traditional approach is often seriously hampered by insufficient price variation observed in survey data. We, therefore, suggest an alternative instrumental variables approach that statistically mimics an experimental study and does not rely on prices as explanatory variables. This approach is applied by means of German survey data. Our estimation results suggest that a reduction in tobacco consumption results in a moderate reduction in alcohol consumption. It is demonstrated that this implies that alcohol and tobacco are complements. Hence, we conclude that successful anti-smoking policies will not result in the unintended side-effect of an increased (ab)use of alcohol.  相似文献   
22.
    
In his comment on Dymski and Pollin the author focuses on the relevant characteristics in the development of OECD countries as well as differences between the performance of North American and European economies in recent years. Emphasis is put on output and productivity growth and employment and real wage experiences. The paper discusses Verdoorn' law and the question of how real phenomena are linked to monetary ones, in particular the financial constraints on full employment policies.  相似文献   
23.
Learning spillovers in the production of EPROMs areinvestigated. It turns out that spillovers aresignificant, even though internal learning is thepredominant source of learning. Concerning externallearning, it does not appear to particularly matterwhether this comes from domestic rivals or foreigncompanies. There is some indication that Japanesecompanies have a steeper learning curve and with somegenerations are better able to appropriate externallearning from foreigners. Intergenerational learningis pervasive, which seems to provide competitiveadvantages to first movers. It could explain thepersistence of leadership of Intel in this industryacross a series of generations. Moreover, it coulddeliver scope for policy intervention.  相似文献   
24.
    
We analyse the adjustment dynamics from a short‐term to a medium‐term equilibrium in a standard AS‐AD model à la Blanchard (2006, Macroeconomics, 4th edn, Prentice‐Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ) for an open economy with fixed and flexible exchange rates. An explicit analysis suggests the local stability of the medium‐term equilibrium. However, an overshooting adjustment dynamics is possible for the exchange rate, a result that directly relates to the famous Dornbusch (1976, Journal of Political Economy, 84, pp. 1161–1176) analysis. In contrast to the latter, in the Blanchard framework it is obtained without assuming rational expectations and without relying upon saddle‐path stability.  相似文献   
25.
As life expectancy increases and fertility declines, population aging puts pressure on the financing of welfare states in Europe and other developed countries. Given that immigrant workers are younger than the domestic population, a continuous flow of immigrants reduces the old-age dependency ratio and improves financing. Existing general equilibrium estimates of the public finance contribution of migration, performed with different models, are not comparable across countries and sometimes differ even in sign. We use the same overlapping-generations model with a detailed representation of institutions and labor market activity to provide comparable estimates of the impact of immigration on public finance in four European countries. We find that future projected immigration flows are equivalent to 14.3 % points labor income taxes in Austria, 7.3 points in Germany, 6.2 points in the UK and 1.7 points in Poland in 2060. These differences are due to the projected volume of immigration and institutional setups, among other factors. For comparable volumes of immigration, future flows have largest impact in Germany and smallest in the UK.  相似文献   
26.
Abstract

Given a characteristic functionφ(t) we want to calculate the corresponding distribution function. For the sake of simplicity we will assume that the mean value of the distribution is zero, i.e. that φ'(0) =0. For these calculations we will use the following formula where The dash on the summation sign indicates that the term corresponding to k = 0 is missing.  相似文献   
27.
28.
29.
30.
Motivated by models of worker flows, we argue in this paper that monopsonistic discrimination may be a substantial factor behind the overall gender wage gap. Using matched employer–employee data from Norway, we estimate establishment-specific wage premiums separately for men and women, conditioning on fixed individual effects. Regressions of worker turnover on the wage premium identify less wage elastic labour supply facing each establishment of women than that of men. Workforce gender composition is strongly related to employers' wage policies. The results suggest that 70–90% of the gender wage gap for low-educated workers may be attributed to differences in labour market frictions between men and women, while the similar figures for high-educated workers ranges from 20 to 70%.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号