全文获取类型
收费全文 | 16912篇 |
免费 | 5篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2659篇 |
工业经济 | 762篇 |
计划管理 | 2595篇 |
经济学 | 3919篇 |
综合类 | 482篇 |
运输经济 | 3篇 |
旅游经济 | 1篇 |
贸易经济 | 4489篇 |
农业经济 | 17篇 |
经济概况 | 1374篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 572篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 2篇 |
2023年 | 3篇 |
2022年 | 3篇 |
2020年 | 7篇 |
2019年 | 7篇 |
2018年 | 2305篇 |
2017年 | 2057篇 |
2016年 | 1210篇 |
2015年 | 95篇 |
2014年 | 93篇 |
2013年 | 67篇 |
2012年 | 434篇 |
2011年 | 1946篇 |
2010年 | 1833篇 |
2009年 | 1519篇 |
2008年 | 1520篇 |
2007年 | 1874篇 |
2006年 | 69篇 |
2005年 | 395篇 |
2004年 | 468篇 |
2003年 | 551篇 |
2002年 | 253篇 |
2001年 | 62篇 |
2000年 | 51篇 |
1998年 | 18篇 |
1997年 | 3篇 |
1996年 | 15篇 |
1995年 | 7篇 |
1994年 | 3篇 |
1993年 | 2篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1989年 | 2篇 |
1988年 | 1篇 |
1987年 | 2篇 |
1986年 | 14篇 |
1984年 | 1篇 |
1983年 | 4篇 |
1982年 | 1篇 |
1981年 | 3篇 |
1979年 | 1篇 |
1978年 | 2篇 |
1977年 | 2篇 |
1976年 | 1篇 |
1975年 | 2篇 |
1973年 | 1篇 |
1969年 | 2篇 |
1944年 | 1篇 |
1939年 | 1篇 |
1926年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
41.
Paul van den Noord 《Empirica》2011,38(1):19-51
The fiscal cost of the financial and economic crisis in Europe is huge. The paper provides provisional estimates of this cost
and looks at its implications for the sustainability of public finances, taking into account also the impact of aging populations.
The historical experience suggests that economic growth is persistently lowered in the aftermath of financial crisis, making
fiscal consolidation more difficult yet all the more essential. Meanwhile the timing of the exit from fiscal stimulus and
subsequent fiscal consolidation must reconcile sustainability and stabilisation goals—a delicate balancing act. The paper
will argue in favour of structural reform to boost the economic growth potential alongside fiscal consolidation. The fiscal
coordination framework in the EU, together with the Europe 2020 strategy, is seen to underpin this approach. 相似文献
42.
Robert F. GarnettJr. 《The Review of Austrian Economics》2011,24(1):71-76
Peter Boettke (2007) argues that economists need not act pluralistically in order for pluralism to thrive in the marketplace of economic ideas.
From a market process perspective, Boettke sees intellectual diversity and openness as catallactic outputs, not inputs—emergent
by-products of academic specialization and trade. To expect individual scholars to behave in a pluralistic manner is unnecessary
and “completely inappropriate” since it detracts from their central task: “to commit themselves to an approach and pursue
it doggedly, even in the face of great doubt and resistance by one’s peers” (Boettke 2007). This paper proposes a Smithian revision of Boettke’s position. The author argues that scholarly pluralism is best understood
as a constitutional rule of academic life—a virtue ethic that promotes learning and intellectual freedom by mitigating tyranny
and autarky in the republic of science. Drawing from the writings of Adam Smith, Friedrich Hayek, Deirdre McCloskey, Bruce
Caldwell, James Buchanan, Don Lavoie, and Boettke himself, the author argues that scholarly pluralism has been, and continues
to be, a necessary condition for the flourishing of Austrian economists as free, responsible, efficacious thinkers. 相似文献
43.
Bryan C. McCannon 《Journal of Economics》2007,92(1):67-88
Rock Paper Scissors is used to resolve conflict when a compromise is not possible. Individuals playing ``games' tend to have
biases they prefer to play. I show that Rock Paper Scissors with biased players results in a player with a high valuation
for winning being victorious with a probability greater than a player with a low valuation. Thus, it frequently achieves the
efficient outcome. Furthermore, as the benefit to victory increases for all players, victory for each player becomes equally
likely. Therefore, it is often efficient for minor conflicts while it performs no better than a coin-flip for major conflicts.
相似文献
44.
Thijs Dekker Roy Brouwer Marjan Hofkes Klaus Moeltner 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2011,49(4):597-624
This paper presents the first value of statistical life (VSL) meta-analysis that empirically estimates correction factors
for ‘out of context’ benefits transfer (BT) purposes. In the field of mortality risk reductions elicited willingness to pay
values in one risk context, say road safety, are frequently applied in other risk contexts like air pollution. However, differences
in risk perception and the population at risk across contexts are likely to result in diverging VSL estimates. In a meta-analysis
of 26 international stated preference studies, a Bayesian model is estimated regressing contingent values for mortality risk
reductions, originating from three different risk contexts, on the characteristics of the risk reduction itself and additional
variables characterizing the underlying studies. A willingness to pay (WTP) premium for mortality risk reductions in the air
pollution and general mortality risk context relative to improving road safety is observed. Evaluated at the mean, road safety
VSL estimates should be multiplied by a factor 1.8 before being applicable in the air pollution context. Moreover, in an illustrative
BT exercise we find limited overlap in the set of context specific predictive VSL distributions. Consequently, ‘out of context’
BT results in a substantial over- or underestimation of the VSL. 相似文献
45.
Mario González María del Mar Alonso-Almeida David Dominguez 《Quality and Quantity》2018,52(3):1041-1055
This study maps the General Reporting Initiative (GRI) relations for a set of global enterprises. Enterprise interrelationships are built using the Mutual Information (MI) of the data reported by enterprises. From the MI topology, we describe interrelationships among the enterprises using chord diagrams to represent the inter- and intra-connectivity between geographical regions and economic sectors globally, by continent and country. Detailed maps are presented for European and Asian regions/sectors, including the relationship between Europe and Asia’s top reporting countries. Our findings reinforce previous research regarding the role of Europe as a driver of sustainability and its influence worldwide. We also determined that Spain is a major player in Europe and that Northern Europe does not have the assumed leading role mentioned in related studies. Eastern Asia is, by far, the leader of the region, and the GRI maps demonstrate the preponderant role of China in the region and the minimal role of India. MI topology maps outline the behavior of the economic sectors, for all the studied regions. Furthermore, a measure that relates the inter- to intra-connections is presented to describe the internal an external relationships among regions/sectors. 相似文献
46.
Brigitte Hoogendoorn Cornelius A. Rietveld André van Stel 《Journal of Evolutionary Economics》2016,26(3):519-550
This cross-country study adopts a competing theories approach in which both a value perspective and a social capital perspective are used to understand the relation between religion and a country’s business ownership rate. We distinguish among four dimensions of religion: belonging to a religious denomination, believing certain religious propositions, bonding to religious practices, and behaving in a religious manner. An empirical analysis of data from 30 OECD countries with multiple data points per country covering the period 1984–2010 suggests a positive relationship between religion and business ownership based on those dimensions that reflect the internal aspects of religiosity (i.e., believing and behaving). We do not observe a significant association for those dimensions that reflect more external aspects of religion (i.e., belonging and bonding). These results suggest that the social capital perspective prevails the value perspective, at least when internal aspects of religiosity are concerned. More generally, our study demonstrates the importance of distinguishing between different dimensions of religion when investigating the link between religion and entrepreneurship. 相似文献
47.
Richard A. Epstein 《Journal of Bioeconomics》2008,10(3):279-285
This article critiques the efforts by Janet Landa, David Sloan Wilson and others to use group selection paradigms to explain
the success of homogenous middlemen groups (HMGs). It argues that group selection theory cannot explain the conflicts of interests
that arise within HMGs or why they dissolve in certain occasions. Landa’s earlier explanations, which stressed the combination
of genetic (kinship) and social bonds in the creation of trust and cooperation in the extension of credit and the creation
of local public goods, better predicts both the strength and weaknesses of HMGs.
相似文献
48.
Differentiating ambiguity: an expository note 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Ghirardato et al. J Econ Theory 118:133–173, 2004 propose a method for distinguishing between perceived ambiguity and the
decision-maker’s reaction to it. They study a general class of preferences which they refer to as invariant biseparable. This class includes CEU and MEU. This note presents some examples which illustrate their results.
Research supported by ESRC grant no. RES-000-22-0650. For comments and discussion we would like to thank Klaus Nehring and
a seminar audience at ESEM, Vienna 2006. 相似文献
49.
Aditya Bhattacharjea 《Review of Industrial Organization》2017,51(2):173-191
The starting point of this paper is a January 1977 judgment of the Indian Supreme Court, which applied the rule of reason to vertical restraints and anticipated many of the arguments of the Sylvania judgment. After summarizing the background of the Indian case, I set out the main points of similarity and difference between the two judgments, and finally assess the somewhat erratic influence of post-Sylvania antitrust thinking on Indian competition law and jurisprudence. 相似文献
50.
Carson W. Bays 《International Advances in Economic Research》2007,13(1):81-96
The idea that changes in Supreme Court decision rules should have measurable effects on the volume of cases litigated has
a compelling plausibility, and several models of litigation predict this result. The prediction is a fragile one, however,
because it implies very restrictive assumptions about the probability distributions of the cases subject to dispute. The period
studied includes four Supreme Court decisions widely regarded as changing the rules and altering the level of uncertainty
surrounding the legality of the anti-tying provisions of the antitrust laws. Broad trends in antitrust activity generally
and changes in firm profitability statistically explain over three-quarters of the observed variation in tying litigation.
Changes in legal precedent have only modest effects upon litigation.
相似文献
Carson W. BaysEmail: |