全文获取类型
收费全文 | 19282篇 |
免费 | 109篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 3154篇 |
工业经济 | 930篇 |
计划管理 | 2904篇 |
经济学 | 4339篇 |
综合类 | 499篇 |
运输经济 | 56篇 |
旅游经济 | 253篇 |
贸易经济 | 5048篇 |
农业经济 | 43篇 |
经济概况 | 1544篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 577篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 15篇 |
2023年 | 34篇 |
2022年 | 23篇 |
2021年 | 47篇 |
2020年 | 90篇 |
2019年 | 192篇 |
2018年 | 2448篇 |
2017年 | 2195篇 |
2016年 | 1312篇 |
2015年 | 172篇 |
2014年 | 196篇 |
2013年 | 510篇 |
2012年 | 564篇 |
2011年 | 2050篇 |
2010年 | 1929篇 |
2009年 | 1628篇 |
2008年 | 1590篇 |
2007年 | 1929篇 |
2006年 | 112篇 |
2005年 | 439篇 |
2004年 | 512篇 |
2003年 | 594篇 |
2002年 | 288篇 |
2001年 | 95篇 |
2000年 | 76篇 |
1999年 | 40篇 |
1998年 | 42篇 |
1997年 | 26篇 |
1996年 | 39篇 |
1995年 | 17篇 |
1994年 | 19篇 |
1993年 | 18篇 |
1992年 | 14篇 |
1991年 | 17篇 |
1990年 | 10篇 |
1989年 | 9篇 |
1988年 | 11篇 |
1987年 | 8篇 |
1986年 | 18篇 |
1985年 | 6篇 |
1984年 | 6篇 |
1983年 | 9篇 |
1981年 | 5篇 |
1980年 | 6篇 |
1979年 | 9篇 |
1978年 | 3篇 |
1977年 | 5篇 |
1976年 | 3篇 |
1975年 | 3篇 |
1974年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
81.
Tommaso Gabrieli Keith Pilbeam Bingxi Shi 《International Economics and Economic Policy》2018,15(2):429-447
This paper empirically analyses the relationship between the shadow banking system and implementation of monetary policy in China using the VECM methodology. We show that an increase in the size of shadow banking sector increases the independence of bank lending from the policies of the People Bank of China. We also find that Shadow Banking works in an asymmetric fashion in that it amplifies increases in the money supply but weakens the effects of restrictive interest rate-based monetary policy decisions. 相似文献
82.
Frederik Stender 《International Economics and Economic Policy》2018,15(2):501-522
This paper aims at unveiling the roots of integration-induced trade effects for MERCOSUR. For this purpose, its methodology combines previous dummy-variables- and continuous variable approaches to identifying trade creation and trade diversion effects in a gravity model framework. Applying a straightforward accounting exercise to the integration-induced trade effects which are found for MERCOSUR en bloc, two results are central: Firstly, with sectoral exceptions, I generally identify pure trade creating effects on the import side but also find trade diversion with associate countries when refining extra-bloc country status. Secondly, while extra-bloc import growth seems to be driven predominantly by non-tariff determinants, trade creation in pooled commodity imports for the largest fraction stems from differences in the tariff treatment between trading partners. 相似文献
83.
The paper shows that currencies of countries with persistent current account surpluses and high foreign-currency denominated assets, such as the Swiss franc and the Japanese yen, are under persistent appreciation pressure, particularly when the centres of the world monetary system follow expansionary monetary policies. This limits the choice of exchange rate regime. Given flexible exchange rates, a negative risk premium on the domestic interest rate can emerge. Empirical estimations provide mixed evidence for a negative impact of net foreign asset positions and exchange rate uncertainty on interest rates of international creditor countries at the periphery of the world monetary system. 相似文献
84.
Manjong Lee 《Open Economies Review》2008,19(1):21-42
Previous studies that compare a uniform money with separate monies used models in which money is the only asset and in which
individuals hold either zero or one unit of money. Here, the comparison is made using a model in which money coexists with
a higher-return asset and in which individuals are permitted to hold richer portfolios of assets. The results show that a
general conclusion is not possible. A uniform money has a higher expected utility than do separate monies in many examples.
However, when the discount on bonds and uncertainty about the nationality of the trading partner are sufficiently high, then
there are examples in which separate monies are better.
相似文献
Manjong LeeEmail: |
85.
This paper empirically investigates the demand for international reserves (and foreign exchange reserves) during fixed and
floating exchange rates periods in three developing countries: Kenya, Mexico and Philippines. Based on theoretical models,
three factors are identified as important for the demand of international reserves and foreign reserves: average propensity
to import, volume of imports and variability of reserves. The paper employs the cointegration methodology and error correction
method to investigate the relationships. Cointegration tests results indicate a reliable long-run stationary relationship
between the international reserves (and foreign exchange reserves) and the stated explanatory variables across countries and
sub-periods of fixed and clean float. The error correction results indicate causality from the explanatory variables to the
reserves during both the short and long run. This is true during both the fixed and the floating periods.
相似文献
Mohammad Hasan (Corresponding author)Email: |
86.
Jesus M. Valencia 《Atlantic Economic Journal》2008,36(2):247-260
Using data gathered by the author in two communities in Southwestern Colombia, this paper tests a model of migration which
incorporates relative deprivation as one of many possible reasons to migrate. The study finds that the product of relative
deprivation and family income not only has a sensible interpretation; it is a better predictor of migration than its two component
variables alone. Results also show that families with the highest propensities to migrate are those with the most to gain
in terms of being better able to reduce relative deprivation through successful migration. These families, however, are neither
at the bottom nor at the top of the income distribution in their communities. The study also finds that those most likely
to migrate to the USA conform most closely to the immigration policies of the USA.
相似文献
Jesus M. ValenciaEmail: |
87.
In this paper we test the well-known hypothesis of Obstfeld and Rogoff (NBER Macroeconomics Annual 7777:339–390, 2000) that trade costs are the key to explaining the so-called Feldstein–Horioka puzzle. Our approach has a number of novel features.
First, we focus on the interrelationship between trade costs, the trade account and the Feldstein–Horioka puzzle. Second,
we use the gravity model to estimate the effect of trade costs on bilateral trade and, third, we show how bilateral trade
can be used to draw inferences about desired trade balances and desired intertemporal trade. Our econometric results provide
strong support for the Obstfeld and Rogoff hypothesis and we are also able to reconcile our results with the so-called home
bias puzzle.
相似文献
Jacques Melitz (Corresponding author)Email: |
88.
This paper analyses both quarterly data from the Confederation of British Industry (CBI) Survey on respondents’ expectations
of recent and forthcoming manufacturing output and monthly Office of National Statistics (ONS) figures on actual manufacturing
output within the UK. Quarterly output expectations of the CBI manufacturers are explained from the monthly ONS observations
using a bounded rationality approach. The logistic formulation models the diffusion process across respondents. There is a
backward-looking CBI Survey perspective, explained by past ONS observations, and a forward-looking perspective, explained
from future ONS statistics. Also, the forecasting of monthly manufacturing output from earlier values, along with the quarterly
CBI Survey information, is examined and tested against the alternative Pesaran/Thomas method. The study provides econometric
evidence for the validity of the logistic model and shows that bounded rationality can explain the formation of predictions
among business managers in the UK manufacturing sector. The emerging consensus from the literature, supported by this paper,
is that the logistic format is a superior approximation to the true data generating process compared with the earlier standard
Anderson/Pesaran/Thomas approach. An adjustment to the Survey is used, which achieves perfect symmetry with up and down versions
of the data. The benefits of this adjustment are tested in the forecasting section.
相似文献
David BywatersEmail: |
89.
Nejat Anbarci 《Atlantic Economic Journal》2008,36(3):293-299
It is a well-known fact that several prominent bargaining solutions are responsive to changes in status-quo (i.e., disagreement
or fallback) payoffs. When an agent’s status-quo payoff increases, his solution payoff either stays the same or increases.
A fully general result for these solutions’ status-quo point ranking is impossible to establish. In this paper, using an important
class of bargaining problems, a ranking of the relative status-quo point responsiveness of prominent bargaining solutions
is obtained. Using the Constant Elasticity of Substitution class of bargaining problems, regardless of the concavity of the
Pareto frontier and the level of increase in one’s status-quo payoff, we find the equal gains solution is the most responsive
with respect to changes in status-quo payoffs, followed by the Nash solution. The equal sacrifice solutions is the least responsive,
followed by the Kalai/Smorodinsky solution.
相似文献
Nejat AnbarciEmail: |
90.