全文获取类型
收费全文 | 17231篇 |
免费 | 14篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2734篇 |
工业经济 | 784篇 |
计划管理 | 2630篇 |
经济学 | 3971篇 |
综合类 | 482篇 |
运输经济 | 15篇 |
旅游经济 | 18篇 |
贸易经济 | 4573篇 |
农业经济 | 23篇 |
经济概况 | 1397篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 574篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 2篇 |
2021年 | 4篇 |
2020年 | 13篇 |
2019年 | 14篇 |
2018年 | 2311篇 |
2017年 | 2063篇 |
2016年 | 1217篇 |
2015年 | 100篇 |
2014年 | 100篇 |
2013年 | 136篇 |
2012年 | 452篇 |
2011年 | 1962篇 |
2010年 | 1861篇 |
2009年 | 1538篇 |
2008年 | 1526篇 |
2007年 | 1880篇 |
2006年 | 83篇 |
2005年 | 403篇 |
2004年 | 484篇 |
2003年 | 569篇 |
2002年 | 263篇 |
2001年 | 76篇 |
2000年 | 60篇 |
1999年 | 13篇 |
1998年 | 24篇 |
1997年 | 9篇 |
1996年 | 21篇 |
1995年 | 5篇 |
1994年 | 10篇 |
1993年 | 1篇 |
1992年 | 5篇 |
1991年 | 1篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1988年 | 1篇 |
1987年 | 2篇 |
1986年 | 14篇 |
1985年 | 1篇 |
1984年 | 2篇 |
1983年 | 1篇 |
1982年 | 2篇 |
1980年 | 4篇 |
1979年 | 2篇 |
1978年 | 2篇 |
1977年 | 1篇 |
1972年 | 1篇 |
1971年 | 2篇 |
1970年 | 1篇 |
1956年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
131.
Jan Wenzelburger 《Annals of Finance》2010,6(2):221-239
This paper resolves two issues regarding the traditional capital asset pricing model with one risk-free asset which seem to have been overlooked in the literature. First, it provides an elementary and complete proof of the two-fund separation theorem which accounts for the fact that asset demand may become undefined if the limiting slopes of the investor’s indifference curves are finite. Second, it shows that an additional limiting condition on investors’ risk aversions is generally necessary to guarantee existence of an equilibrium. Moreover, a generalized existence result is formulated which includes investors who in equilibrium may not invest in risky assets and a simple condition ensuring positive equilibrium asset prices is given. 相似文献
132.
133.
N. K. Chidambaran Kose John Zhaoyun Shangguan Gopala Vasudevan 《Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting》2010,34(3):327-349
We study mergers and acquisition during the period from 1988 to 2005 and examine the impact of merger market intensity, i.e., merger waves, on the means of payment and the returns to target and acquirer shareholders. We use two proxies to measure the intensity of the merger market—the number of mergers in the trailing 12-month period prior to a merger and the total dollar volume of mergers in the trailing 12-month period prior to a merger—and use these measures to define hot and cold merger markets. We find that stock financing is more common after a stock price run-up for the acquiring firm and in hot merger markets. We also find that the acquisition premium is larger in hot merger markets. Returns to acquiring company shareholders are lower for stock financed mergers and are lower when merger markets are intense. Our results are consistent with the predictions of the behavioral theory for merger waves. 相似文献
134.
Michael A. Goldstein Andriy V. Shkilko Bonnie F. Van Ness Robert A. Van Ness 《Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting》2010,35(4):371-391
Blume and Goldstein (J Finance 52:221–244, 1997) suggest that quote competition between trading venues may diminish following tick size reductions. We test this suggestion
by studying the competitive landscape in the NYSE-listed stocks before and after decimalization. We find that NBBO (National
Best Bid and Offer) participation by non-NYSE venues declines following decimalization consistent with the prediction. At
the same time, the importance of quote competitiveness in attracting order flow increases. In addition, although not as active
in determining and maintaining the best quotes under decimals, non-NYSE venues become more active in price discovery. Finally,
decimalization leads to lower trading costs and to smaller differences in trading costs across trading venues. 相似文献
135.
We re-examine a key result in the optimal UI literature that benefits should decline over time. We show that when the population is heterogeneous, Pareto-efficiency may call for multiple payment schedules, some with benefits that fall over time and some with benefits that rise over time. 相似文献
136.
Steven C. Bourassa Martin Hoesli 《The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics》2010,40(3):286-309
At less than 34%, Switzerland has the lowest home ownership rate in Western Europe. This may seem odd given the economic strength
of the country. We use household survey data for five Swiss cantons to explore some possible reasons for this. We estimate
a tenure choice equation that allows us to analyze the impacts of a number of key variables on the ownership rate. We pay
particular attention to the relative cost of owning and renting, which is a function of house prices, rents, and the user
cost of owning. The latter is a function of income tax policy and expected house price inflation, among other things. We also
measure mortgage underwriting criteria and consider rent control and other policies affecting rental housing. By simulating
a number of hypothetical changes to taxation and other policies, underwriting criteria, and price levels, we assess the importance
of these variables in explaining the ownership rate. We conclude that high house prices—relative to household incomes and
wealth—and the tax on imputed rent are the most important causes of Switzerland’s low ownership rate. 相似文献
137.
This paper applies the Taiwan electronics industry data to detect the discriminatory powers of Logit, KMV, and zero-price probability (ZPP) models that represent respectively the regressive fitting model, the option-based pricing model, and the GARCH time series simulation model. In our circumstances, according to cumulative accuracy profile, receiver operating characteristic, and even Brier score, the KMV performs the worst. The disadvantages for KMV are that the equity market exists some nonlinear characteristics, the unknown market value of asset affected by the change of capital structure is not exogenous, and the failure point is difficult to be estimated correctly. Besides, KMV is however too simple to model the fluctuation of the equity value as the GARCH does. On the other hand, the Logit performs above average. To preclude over-fitting and keep model parsimonious, two significant factors are extracted from as many as forty financial variables for the logistic regression on binary failure data. The result of Logit training has perfect discrimination. However, for the post-sample data, the fitting to categorical but not ordinal data makes Logit have the divergent failure predicted probabilities and highest Briser Score. In practical, ZPP GARCHNorm uses just equity value to predict firm failure but it performs remarkably well supposing that downward price trend or volatility persistence in stock price changes is appropriately caught. It implies that the distorted signals such as overreaction of traders and insider trading would definitely impair the ZPP GARCHNorm. Nevertheless, the larger type I error than type II error in all models indicates that the prediction of non-failed firms should be more examined further than that of failed firms. 相似文献
138.
139.
This study examines the cost efficiency of 39 microfinance institutions across Africa, Asia and the Latin America using non-parametric data envelopment analysis. Our findings show non-governmental microfinance institutions particularly; under production approach, are the most efficient and this result is consistent with their fulfillment of dual objectives: alleviating poverty and simultaneously achieving financial sustainability. However, bank-microfinance institutions also outperform in the measure of efficiency under intermediation approach. This result reflects that banks are the financial intermediaries and have access to local capital market. It may be possible that bank-microfinance institutions may outperform the non-governmental microfinance institutions in the long run. 相似文献
140.
Wolf Wagner 《Journal of Financial Services Research》2010,37(1):71-81
Recent literature (Boyd and De Nicoló, J Finance 60:1329–1343, 2005) has argued that competition in the loan market lowers bank risk by reducing the risk-taking incentives of borrowers. Using
a model where competition arises from falling switching costs for entrepreneurs, we show that the impact of loan market competition
on banks is reversed if banks can adjust their loan portfolios. The reason is that when borrowers become safer, banks want
to offset the effect on their balance sheet and switch to higher-risk lending. They even overcompensate the effect of safer
borrowers because loan market competition erodes their franchise values and thus increases their risk-taking incentives. 相似文献