全文获取类型
收费全文 | 11663篇 |
免费 | 1155篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2025篇 |
工业经济 | 939篇 |
计划管理 | 2332篇 |
经济学 | 2655篇 |
综合类 | 47篇 |
运输经济 | 187篇 |
旅游经济 | 168篇 |
贸易经济 | 2606篇 |
农业经济 | 553篇 |
经济概况 | 1202篇 |
邮电经济 | 104篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 123篇 |
2020年 | 254篇 |
2019年 | 602篇 |
2018年 | 388篇 |
2017年 | 532篇 |
2016年 | 534篇 |
2015年 | 516篇 |
2014年 | 568篇 |
2013年 | 1302篇 |
2012年 | 638篇 |
2011年 | 621篇 |
2010年 | 564篇 |
2009年 | 511篇 |
2008年 | 482篇 |
2007年 | 418篇 |
2006年 | 396篇 |
2005年 | 356篇 |
2004年 | 317篇 |
2003年 | 319篇 |
2002年 | 281篇 |
2001年 | 260篇 |
2000年 | 231篇 |
1999年 | 174篇 |
1998年 | 142篇 |
1997年 | 146篇 |
1996年 | 152篇 |
1995年 | 112篇 |
1994年 | 118篇 |
1993年 | 119篇 |
1992年 | 99篇 |
1991年 | 93篇 |
1990年 | 90篇 |
1989年 | 81篇 |
1988年 | 72篇 |
1987年 | 63篇 |
1986年 | 71篇 |
1985年 | 104篇 |
1984年 | 101篇 |
1983年 | 82篇 |
1982年 | 78篇 |
1981年 | 74篇 |
1980年 | 84篇 |
1979年 | 69篇 |
1978年 | 54篇 |
1977年 | 52篇 |
1976年 | 47篇 |
1975年 | 40篇 |
1974年 | 35篇 |
1973年 | 39篇 |
1972年 | 34篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
51.
Peter M. Nomikos 《Intereconomics》1981,16(6):292-294
The world’s energy supplies are dependent not only on the producer countries’ production capacities and policies but also on adequate transport facilities. In fact, a shortage of vessels able to carry coal is widely expected to be a major bottleneck for the substitution of oil by coal on a large scale. Shipowner Peter M. Nomikos holds a different view. 相似文献
52.
Yiwei Dou Ole‐Kristian Hope Wayne B. Thomas Youli Zou 《Contemporary Accounting Research》2018,35(2):1004-1028
Recent theoretical and empirical studies suggest that blockholders (shareholders with ownership ≥ 5 percent) exert governance through the threat of exit. Blockholders have strong incentives to gather private information and sell their shares when managers are perceived to underperform. To prevent blockholders from selling their shares and the firm from suffering a stock price decline, managers align their actions with the interests of shareholders. As a result of the greater manager‐shareholder alignment, managers' actions are more likely to be in shareholders' best interest, and consequently there is less need for managers to manipulate earnings. Consistent with these predictions from economic theory, we find evidence that as exit threat increases, firms have higher financial reporting quality. Theory also predicts that the impact of blockholders' exit threat on financial reporting quality (FRQ) should increase as the manager's wealth is tied more closely to the stock price, and this is what we find. Our study contributes to the research on the impact of shareholders on FRQ and to an emerging literature on the impact of blockholders in financial markets. Blockholders play an important role in managers' reporting outcomes through their actions as informed investors. 相似文献
53.
We exploit an exogenous shock to analyst coverage as a result of brokerage house mergers and closures to examine whether financial analysts influence the tax‐planning activities of the firms they cover. Using a difference‐in‐differences design, we find that, on average, firms affected by broker mergers and/or closures experience a reduction in their GAAP (cash) effective tax rates (ETR) of 2.5 percent (2.6 percent), relative to control firms, translating into average tax expense (cash tax) savings of $34 ($35) million. The treatment effect is more pronounced among firms with lower pre‐event analyst coverage. To explore how analysts affect tax planning, we further document that the treatment effect is greater among firms that lose an analyst who provided an implied ETR forecast in the past, suggesting that analysts influence tax planning via their tax‐specific research efforts. In addition, we find that after merger/closure, weakly governed firms increase their use of aggressive tax strategies, and financially distressed firms experience a larger reduction of cash effective tax rates, relative to control firms. Overall, we provide evidence that a shock to analyst coverage sufficiently changes the cost‐benefit trade‐off of tax planning. 相似文献
54.
Age‐heaping‐based numeracy indicators have served as valuable tools to derive basic human capital estimates, especially for periods where other indicators are unavailable. However, the accuracy of individual age statements usually remains unknown, and due to the lack of precise information it can only be assumed that excessive occurrence of multiples of five in age distributions reflects inferior numerical skills. This article addresses this lacuna by identifying 162 individuals in two independent data sources: self‐reported age statements and independently kept records which are based on family heritage books and church registers. This method makes it possible to identify individual misreporting and the degree of accuracy of each individual. Findings show that not everyone who reported a multiple of five was reporting an incorrect age, nor was it the case that everyone who reported an age that was not a multiple of five was reporting an accurate age. The empirical analysis shows that the commonly used binary numeracy indicator is correlated with the observed degree of accuracy in age statements, and that a more sophisticated occupational background reduces this inaccuracy. These results tentatively suggest that the commonly used binary indicator measuring age heaping is a valuable proxy for numerical skills and occupational background in a population. 相似文献
55.
56.
57.
Based on pooled register data from Norway and Sweden, we findthat differences in unemployment duration patterns reflect dissimilaritiesin unemployment insurance (UI) systems in a way that convincinglyestablishes the link between economic incentives and job searchbehaviour. Specifically, UI benefits are relatively more generousfor low-income workers in Sweden than in Norway, leading torelatively longer unemployment spells for low-income workersin Sweden. Based on the between-countries variation in replacementratios, we find that the elasticity of the outflow rate frominsured unemployment with respect to the replacement ratio isapproximately one in Norway and 0.5 in Sweden. 相似文献
58.
Feldstein and Horioka (Econ J 90:314–329, 1980) observed that saving and investment move closely together in the major OECD
countries. This finding is a puzzle if national economies are characterized by one sector neoclassical production functions—with
diminishing returns to capital, a high level of savings in a country should create an incentive to export capital. In this
paper, we show that this incentive disappears in the presence of multiple sectors with differing capital intensities. In a
high saving country, national capital can be absorbed domestically without a decline in its marginal product through a shift
in the sectoral composition of national production towards capital intensive sectors. This is nothing but the well-known Rybczynski
effect. We present a modified version of the standard Heckscher–Ohlin (HO) Model to show that very small barriers to capital
mobility are enough to force national savings to stay within the country of origin. We also argue that, while the assumptions
of this model may appear special, they are not unrealistic for the developed countries in the Feldstein Horioka study. Some
historical economic trends are also consistent with the picture presented in this paper. Finally, the paper shows that the
conventional insights from the one sector neoclassical model can be completely overturned in a multi-sector setting when technological
differences are introduced.
相似文献
Ufuk DemirogluEmail: |
59.
60.
Corporate lobbying activities are designed to influence legislators, regulators and courts, presumably to encourage favorable policies and/or outcomes. In dollar terms, corporate lobbying expenditures are typically one or even two orders of magnitude larger than spending by Political Action Committees (PAC), and, unlike PAC donations, lobbying amounts are direct corporate expenditures. We use data made available by the Lobbying Disclosure Act of 1995 to examine this more pervasive form of corporate political activity. We find that, on average, lobbying is positively related to accounting and market measures of financial performance. These results are robust across a number of empirical specifications. We also report market performance evidence using a portfolio approach. We find that portfolios of firms with the highest lobbying intensities significantly outperform their benchmarks in the three years following portfolio formation. 相似文献