全文获取类型
收费全文 | 1133篇 |
免费 | 10篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 184篇 |
工业经济 | 61篇 |
计划管理 | 175篇 |
经济学 | 323篇 |
综合类 | 9篇 |
运输经济 | 7篇 |
旅游经济 | 14篇 |
贸易经济 | 221篇 |
农业经济 | 36篇 |
经济概况 | 101篇 |
邮电经济 | 12篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 9篇 |
2023年 | 9篇 |
2022年 | 6篇 |
2021年 | 14篇 |
2020年 | 24篇 |
2019年 | 34篇 |
2018年 | 31篇 |
2017年 | 45篇 |
2016年 | 41篇 |
2015年 | 30篇 |
2014年 | 50篇 |
2013年 | 110篇 |
2012年 | 60篇 |
2011年 | 43篇 |
2010年 | 48篇 |
2009年 | 50篇 |
2008年 | 38篇 |
2007年 | 40篇 |
2006年 | 41篇 |
2005年 | 29篇 |
2004年 | 21篇 |
2003年 | 28篇 |
2002年 | 31篇 |
2001年 | 26篇 |
2000年 | 22篇 |
1999年 | 25篇 |
1998年 | 14篇 |
1997年 | 13篇 |
1996年 | 8篇 |
1995年 | 12篇 |
1994年 | 7篇 |
1993年 | 8篇 |
1992年 | 8篇 |
1991年 | 6篇 |
1990年 | 6篇 |
1989年 | 7篇 |
1988年 | 6篇 |
1986年 | 9篇 |
1985年 | 5篇 |
1984年 | 10篇 |
1983年 | 13篇 |
1982年 | 10篇 |
1981年 | 12篇 |
1980年 | 10篇 |
1979年 | 8篇 |
1978年 | 13篇 |
1977年 | 10篇 |
1976年 | 11篇 |
1975年 | 5篇 |
1974年 | 5篇 |
排序方式: 共有1143条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
91.
92.
The purpose in this article is to evaluate the consistency between two measures of unemployment in a cross-country context.
We use the European Community Household Panel to identify unemployment at an individual level based as well on the ILO criteria
for being classified as unemployed as on the individual respondent reporting to be unemployed. This opens a unique opportunity
to compare unemployment measured in two different ways based on a cross European Union panel study covering the years 1994
to 2001. The two main questions addressed in this article are to which extent the two unemployment measures differ and whether
transition rates out of unemployment depend on which concept we use. Both questions are answered in the affirmative. The overall
conclusion is that it is important, especially in some of the EU countries, to include both measures of unemployment as guidelines
and indicators for policy. 相似文献
93.
Using a small empirical model of inflation, output, and money estimated on U.S. data, we compare the relative performance of monetary targeting and inflation targeting. The results show monetary targeting to be quite inefficient, yielding both higher inflation and output variability. This is true even with a nonstochastic money demand formulation. Our results are also robust to using a P∗ model of inflation. Therefore, in these popular frameworks, there is no support for the prominent role given to money growth in the Eurosystem's monetary policy strategy. 相似文献
94.
Young workers in the 1990s can expect greater economic insecurity, as well as lower average earnings, compared to older workers, or compared to the youth of previous decades. The cost of greater insecurity depends upon an individual's probability of unemployment, marginal utility of income gains/losses and the extent to which individuals can smooth consumption over time by borrowing and drawing down assets. Since unemployment insurance cutbacks and higher unemployment have increased the risk exposure of youth, changes in the expected value of their income may understate utility losses as measured by the change in certainty equivalent income.
This paper uses a behavioural microsimulation model to compare the impacts of 1971 and 1994 unemployment insurance legislation and unemployment rates in Canada. It calculates both the expected value of income changes and, using a Stone-Geary utility function, the change in inequality of well-being (as measured by certainty equivalent income) for youth and for prime age workers. Both calculations reveal that youth were disproportionately affected by Canada's changing labour market environment. Very few youth have enough assets to finance consumption during spells of unemployment. 相似文献
This paper uses a behavioural microsimulation model to compare the impacts of 1971 and 1994 unemployment insurance legislation and unemployment rates in Canada. It calculates both the expected value of income changes and, using a Stone-Geary utility function, the change in inequality of well-being (as measured by certainty equivalent income) for youth and for prime age workers. Both calculations reveal that youth were disproportionately affected by Canada's changing labour market environment. Very few youth have enough assets to finance consumption during spells of unemployment. 相似文献
95.
This study focuses on the labour market performance among second‐generation immigrants in Sweden. One motivation behind the analysis is that it gives insight into the long‐term consequences of immigration. Labour market performance relates the probability of having a job, referred to here as a threshold effect and to the differences in income from work, given that a person is in the market and is referred to as an income from work effect. We have shown that a clear threshold effect of being a second‐generation immigrant exists and that different groups of second‐generation immigrants perform differently in the Swedish labour market. 相似文献
96.
Zusammenfassung Sollten direkte oder totale Faktorintensit?ten beim Test der Faktorproportionenhypothese verwendet werden? — Dieser Aufsatz
befa\t sich mit der Faktorproportionenhypothese und den Faktorintensit?ten, mit denen die Hypothese getestet werden kann.
Wenn alle Güter einschlie\lich der Zwischenprodukte handelbar sind und wenn es keine Spezialisierung in der Produktion gibt,
dann sind die direkten Faktorintensit?ten ma\gebend, wenn die Allokation der Bruttoproduktion zwischen den L?ndern erkl?rt
werden soll. Demgegenüber sind die totalen Faktorintensit?ten für die Erkl?rung der Nettohandelsstr?me relevant. Wenn es nichthandelbare
Güter gibt, dann sollten die Faktorintensit?ten der handelbaren Güter so modifiziert werden, da\ sie den direkten Faktorinput
aller nichthandelbaren Güter einschlie\en, die bei der Produktion von handelbaren Gütern verbraucht werden. Die Ergebnisse
zeigen sich in strenger Form, wenn die Anzahl der handelbaren Güter und der Faktoren gleich ist. übersteigt die Anzahl der
handelbaren Güter die der Faktoren, dann besteht eine Tendenz zur Spezialisierung in der Produktion. Liegt dieser Fall der
Spezialisierung vor, werden zudem alle Güter gehandelt und existieren keine nichthandelbaren Güter, besteht immer noch die
Beziehung zwischen den direkten Faktorintensit?ten und der Allokation der Bruttoproduktion, w?hrend die totalen Faktorintensit?ten
mit den Handelsstr?men nicht mehr so deutlich zusammenh?ngen.
Résumé Doit-on appliquer les intensités des facteurs directes ou totales pour tester l’hypothèse des proportions des facteurs? — Cet article s’occupe de l’hypothèse des proportions des facteurs et des intensités des facteurs avec lesquelles on peut la tester. Si tous les biens, les inputs intermédiaires inclus, sont commerces et s’il n’y a pas une spécialisation dans la production, les intensités des facteurs directes sont importantes pour expliquer l’allocation de la production brute parmi des pays; pendant que les intensités des facteurs totales sont d’importance pour expliquer les flux commerciaux nets des biens. De plus, s’il y a des biens non-commercés, les intensités des facteurs des biens commercés devraient être modifiées de manière à inclure les inputs directs des facteurs dans le montant total des biens non-commercés qui sont utilisés dans la production des biens commercés. Ces résultats sont rigoureusement dérivés si les biens commercés et les facteurs sont de même nombre. Si le nombre des biens commercés excède le nombre des facteurs, il y a une tendance à la spécialisation dans la production. Dans ce cas et si tous les biens sont commercés et s’il n’y a pas des biens non-commercés, les intensités des facteurs directes sont encore d’importance pour l’allocation de la production brute, pendant que les intensités des facteurs totales sont moins d’importance pour les flux commerciaux, comparé avec le cas où il n’y a pas une spécialisation dans la production.
Resumen Deberían utilizarse las intensidades de factores directas o totales en los ensayos de la hipótesis de proporción de factores? — Este artículo se ocupa de la hipótesis de proporción de factores y las intensidades de factores con las que las hipótesis pueden ser sometidas a prueba. Si todos los bienes, incluyendo inputs intermedios, son comerciados y no hay especializaci?n en la produeei?n, las intensidades de factores directas son relevantes para explicar la asignaei?n de la produeeión bruta entre países; considerando que las intensidades de factores totales son relevantes para explicar los rlujos netos del comercio de bienes. Más aún, si hay bienes no comerciables, las intensidades de factores de bienes comerciables deberían modificarse de tal manera de incluir los inputs factoriales directos en los montos totales de bienes no comerciables utilizados en la produeeión de bienes comerciables. Estos resultados se muestran rigurosamente para el caso de un númro igual de bienes transables y de factores. Si el número de bienes transables sobrepasa el número de factores, hay una tendencia hacia la especialización en la produeeión. Para tal caso, con comercio en todos los bienes y sin bienes no transables, la intensidad directa de factores est’ aún relacionada con la asignaeión de la produeeión bruta; considerando que las intensidades totales de factores están relacionadas con los flujos comerciales, aunque menos claramente que sin especialización en la produeeión.相似文献
97.
Esben Rahbek Pedersen 《Journal of Business Ethics》2010,91(2):155-166
The purpose of this article is to develop a model of how managers perceive the responsibilities of business towards society. The article is based on the survey responses of more than 1,000 managers in eight large international firms. It is concluded that the managerial perceptions of societal responsibilities differ in some respects from the mainstream models found in the corporate social responsibility (CSR) and business ethics literature. The article is an output of RESPONSE: an EU- and corporate-funded research project on managerial perceptions of CSR. 相似文献
98.
At the end of the eighteenth century, England and France both underwent revolutions: France the French Revolution, England the industrial revolution. This note sheds new light on these contrasting experiences in the histories of England and France by looking at the evolution of real consumer prices in London and Paris in the centuries leading up to 1800. Whilst in London, building workers were facing low and stable consumer prices over the period, leaving plenty of scope for a demand-driven consumer revolution (in particular after 1650), their Parisian counterparts had to engage in a year-long grind to maintain a decent living, and often had to cut consumption to make ends meet. The exercise conducted in the present paper gives a quantitative and economic underpinning to the notion that the French revolution did not arise out of nowhere, but rather had its roots in centuries of hardship amongst working class people as they struggled to make a living. 相似文献
99.
Investment liberalizing countries are often concerned that cross-border mergers and acquisitions, in contrast to greenfield investments, might have an adverse effect on domestic firms and consumers. However, given that domestic assets are sufficiently scarce, we identify a preemption effect and an asset complementarity effect, which imply that the acquisition price is substantially higher than the domestic seller's profits. Moreover, we show that for the acquisition to take place, the MNE must be sufficiently efficient when using the domestic assets, otherwise rivals will expand their business, thereby making the acquisition unprofitable. Consequently, restricting cross-border M&As may also hurt consumers. 相似文献
100.