全文获取类型
收费全文 | 17039篇 |
免费 | 10篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2708篇 |
工业经济 | 793篇 |
计划管理 | 2632篇 |
经济学 | 3905篇 |
综合类 | 486篇 |
运输经济 | 3篇 |
旅游经济 | 3篇 |
贸易经济 | 4523篇 |
农业经济 | 5篇 |
经济概况 | 1375篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 572篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 2篇 |
2021年 | 4篇 |
2020年 | 4篇 |
2019年 | 7篇 |
2018年 | 2308篇 |
2017年 | 2058篇 |
2016年 | 1212篇 |
2015年 | 94篇 |
2014年 | 89篇 |
2013年 | 85篇 |
2012年 | 441篇 |
2011年 | 1948篇 |
2010年 | 1849篇 |
2009年 | 1527篇 |
2008年 | 1519篇 |
2007年 | 1878篇 |
2006年 | 73篇 |
2005年 | 392篇 |
2004年 | 468篇 |
2003年 | 560篇 |
2002年 | 262篇 |
2001年 | 75篇 |
2000年 | 61篇 |
1999年 | 5篇 |
1998年 | 25篇 |
1997年 | 6篇 |
1996年 | 18篇 |
1995年 | 5篇 |
1993年 | 5篇 |
1992年 | 3篇 |
1991年 | 5篇 |
1990年 | 4篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1988年 | 2篇 |
1987年 | 4篇 |
1986年 | 14篇 |
1985年 | 2篇 |
1984年 | 4篇 |
1983年 | 4篇 |
1982年 | 3篇 |
1981年 | 3篇 |
1980年 | 4篇 |
1978年 | 1篇 |
1977年 | 6篇 |
1975年 | 1篇 |
1974年 | 3篇 |
1973年 | 1篇 |
1970年 | 2篇 |
1966年 | 1篇 |
1957年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
61.
Workforce or workfare? The optimal use of work requirements when labour is supplied along the extensive margin 下载免费PDF全文
This paper explores the use of workfare as part of a tax mix when labour supply responses are along the extensive margin. In an economy where the government has a priori chosen any tax‐and‐benefit schedule, we show that, despite their common goal of providing additional incentives for individuals to enter the labour force, workfare and an earned income tax credit are at odds with each other. We also show that, in the presence of an optimal nonlinear income tax, introducing unproductive workfare is always suboptimal when individuals face the same disutility of being on workfare. When this disutility is heterogeneous, unproductive workfare may be a useful policy tool. 相似文献
62.
Aditya Bhattacharjea 《Review of Industrial Organization》2017,51(2):173-191
The starting point of this paper is a January 1977 judgment of the Indian Supreme Court, which applied the rule of reason to vertical restraints and anticipated many of the arguments of the Sylvania judgment. After summarizing the background of the Indian case, I set out the main points of similarity and difference between the two judgments, and finally assess the somewhat erratic influence of post-Sylvania antitrust thinking on Indian competition law and jurisprudence. 相似文献
63.
Carson W. Bays 《International Advances in Economic Research》2007,13(1):81-96
The idea that changes in Supreme Court decision rules should have measurable effects on the volume of cases litigated has
a compelling plausibility, and several models of litigation predict this result. The prediction is a fragile one, however,
because it implies very restrictive assumptions about the probability distributions of the cases subject to dispute. The period
studied includes four Supreme Court decisions widely regarded as changing the rules and altering the level of uncertainty
surrounding the legality of the anti-tying provisions of the antitrust laws. Broad trends in antitrust activity generally
and changes in firm profitability statistically explain over three-quarters of the observed variation in tying litigation.
Changes in legal precedent have only modest effects upon litigation.
相似文献
Carson W. BaysEmail: |
64.
Leland B. Yeager 《The Review of Austrian Economics》2010,23(2):183-191
A prominent philosophical/legal case for requiring 100% bank reserves employs a flawed style of argument. It involves essentialism (criticized by Karl Popper and Joseph Schumpeter), persuasive definitions (identified by Charles L. Stevenson), faulty classification, and the piling up of irrelevant facts and considerations. 相似文献
65.
We consider the game in which b buyers each seek to purchase 1 unit of an indivisible good from s sellers, each of whom has k units to sell. The good is worth 0 to each seller and 1 to each buyer. Using the central limit theorem, and implicitly convergence
to tied down Brownian motion, we find a closed form solution for the limiting Shapley value as s and b increase without bound. This asymptotic value depends upon the seller size k, the limiting ratio b/ks of buyers to items for sale, and the limiting ratio of the excess supply relative to the square root of the number of market participants.
This work was sponsered in part by NSF Grant DMS-03-01795. 相似文献
66.
This paper proposes a generalized spatial panel-data probit model with spatial autocorrelation of the dependent variable, the time-invariant individual shocks, and the remainder disturbances. It proposes its estimation with a Bayesian Markov chain Monte Carlo procedure. Simulation results show that the proposed estimation method performs well in small- to medium-sized samples. This method is then applied to the analysis of export-market participation of 1451 Chinese firms between 2002 and 2006 in the prefecture-level city of Wenzhou in the province of Zhejiang. Empirical results show that two of the three forms of the hypothesized spatial autocorrelation are significant, namely the spatial lag for the dependent variable and the time-invariant firm-specific shocks, but not the time-variant shocks. Ignoring any of these significant spatial effects would lead to misspecification. 相似文献
67.
In time series context, estimation and testing issues with autoregressive and moving average (ARMA) models are well understood. Similar issues in the context of spatial ARMA models for the disturbance of the regression, however, remain largely unexplored. In this paper, we discuss the problems of testing no spatial dependence in the disturbances against the alternative of spatial ARMA process incorporating the possible presence of spatial dependence in the dependent variable. The problems of conducting such a test are twofold. First, under the null hypothesis, the nuisance parameter is not identified, resulting in a singular information matrix (IM), which is a nonregular case in statistical inference. To take account of singular IM, we follow Davies (Biometrika 64(2):247–254, 1977; Biometrika 74(1):33–43, 1987) and propose a test procedure based on the supremum of the Rao score test statistic. Second, the possible presence of spatial lag dependence will have adverse effect on the performance of the test. Using the general test procedure of Bera and Yoon (Econom Theory 9:649–658, 1993) under local misspecification, we avoid the explicit estimation of the spatial autoregressive parameter. Thus our suggested tests are entirely based on ordinary least squares estimation. Tests suggested here can be viewed as a generalization of Anselin et al. (Reg Sci Urban Econ 26:77–104, 1996). We conduct Monte Carlo simulations to investigate the finite sample properties of the proposed tests. Simulation results show that our tests have good finite sample properties both in terms of size and power, compared to other tests in the literature. We also illustrate the applications of our tests through several data sets. 相似文献
68.
69.
Bernhard Hirsch 《Controlling & Management》2007,51(2):88-89
Ohne Zusammenfassung 相似文献
70.
Camelia Bejan 《Economic Theory》2008,37(1):99-118
This paper proposes a model of imperfect competition among privately owned firms that act in the best interest of their shareholders.
The existence of a solution for the model is proved under weaker conditions than the ones generally used in the literature.
In particular, the results did not require the existence of a continuous equilibrium price selection or concavity assumptions
on the profit function.
相似文献