全文获取类型
收费全文 | 580篇 |
免费 | 22篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 67篇 |
工业经济 | 38篇 |
计划管理 | 99篇 |
经济学 | 200篇 |
运输经济 | 5篇 |
旅游经济 | 5篇 |
贸易经济 | 123篇 |
农业经济 | 32篇 |
经济概况 | 33篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 6篇 |
2023年 | 11篇 |
2022年 | 6篇 |
2021年 | 11篇 |
2020年 | 15篇 |
2019年 | 27篇 |
2018年 | 25篇 |
2017年 | 24篇 |
2016年 | 38篇 |
2015年 | 21篇 |
2014年 | 24篇 |
2013年 | 71篇 |
2012年 | 25篇 |
2011年 | 33篇 |
2010年 | 22篇 |
2009年 | 28篇 |
2008年 | 32篇 |
2007年 | 15篇 |
2006年 | 13篇 |
2005年 | 10篇 |
2004年 | 12篇 |
2003年 | 8篇 |
2002年 | 16篇 |
2001年 | 11篇 |
2000年 | 6篇 |
1999年 | 10篇 |
1998年 | 6篇 |
1997年 | 3篇 |
1996年 | 12篇 |
1995年 | 12篇 |
1994年 | 3篇 |
1992年 | 2篇 |
1991年 | 4篇 |
1990年 | 2篇 |
1989年 | 2篇 |
1986年 | 2篇 |
1985年 | 1篇 |
1984年 | 2篇 |
1982年 | 7篇 |
1981年 | 2篇 |
1980年 | 5篇 |
1979年 | 3篇 |
1978年 | 3篇 |
1977年 | 1篇 |
1976年 | 2篇 |
1975年 | 2篇 |
1967年 | 1篇 |
1960年 | 1篇 |
1956年 | 1篇 |
1936年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有602条查询结果,搜索用时 78 毫秒
51.
Mario Larch;Yoto V. Yotov; 《The World Economy》2024,47(5):1771-1799
Starting with Tinbergen (1962, Shaping the world economy: Suggestions for an international economic policy, The Twentieth Century Fund), quantifying the effects of regional trade agreements (RTAs) on international trade flows has always been among the most popular topics in the trade literature. Also not surprisingly, to estimate the effects of RTAs, most researchers and policy analysts have relied on the workhorse model of trade—the gravity equation. Over the past 60 years, there have been many important developments in the RTA literature, both in terms of better methods to quantify their effects, and in terms of more and higher quality data. The objective of this paper is to trace the evolution of the methods and data developments in the RTA literature, from Tinbergen's very first exploration until today, and to critically evaluate their significance for our ability to measure the impact of RTAs (and other policies) on international trade. 相似文献
52.
53.
Mario Mazzocchi Gianluca Stefani Spencer J. Henson 《Journal of Agricultural Economics》2004,55(1):41-58
The paper develops a measure of consumer welfare losses associated with withholding information about a possible link between BSE and vCJD. The Cost of Ignorance (COI) is measured by comparing the utility of the informed choice with the utility of the uninformed choice, under conditions of improved information. Unlike previous work that is largely based on a single equation demand model, the measure is obtained retrieving a cost function from a dynamic Almost Ideal Demand System. The estimated perceived loss for Italian consumers due to delayed information ranges from 12 percent to 54 percent of total meat expenditure, depending on the month assumed to embody correct beliefs about the safety level of beef. 相似文献
54.
In this paper we use global analysis to study the welfare properties of general equilibrium economies with incomplete markets (GEI). Our main result is to show that constrained Pareto optimal equilibria are contained in a submanifold of the equilibrium set. This result is explicitly derived for economies with real assets and fixed aggregate resources, of which real numéraire assets are a special case. As a by product of our analysis, we propose an original global parametrization of the equilibrium set that generalizes to incomplete markets the classical one, first, proposed by Lange [Lange, O., 1942. The foundations of welfare economics. Econometrica 10, 215–228]. 相似文献
55.
Claudia Gabbioneta Royston Greenwood Pietro Mazzola Mario Minoja 《Accounting, Organizations and Society》2013,38(6-7):484-504
This paper examines the relationship between the institutional environment and sustained corporate illegality. We find that cognitive assumptions generate expectations that can, under specific circumstances, induce organizations to amplify illegal actions and that serve to lessen regulatory scrutiny. We also find that, once initiated, illegal actions can become hidden because of institutionalized practices that enable their concealment and that weaken the prospect of detection. These processes and effects are particularly noticeable in networks of professional regulators who become mutually over-confident and over-influenced by each other to the extent that their independent critical assessments and judgements are compromised. Mechanisms of mimetic herding and social humiliation compromise independence of judgement. Networks of interacting professionals are thus vulnerable to a collectively induced lowering of regulatory vigilance. 相似文献
56.
We propose an extension of the standard general equilibrium model with production and incomplete markets to situations in
which (i) private investors have limited information on the returns of specific assets, (ii) managers of firms have limited
information on the preferences of individual shareholders. The extension is obtained by the assumption that firms are not
traded directly but grouped into ‘sectorial’ funds. In our model the financial policy of the firm is not irrelevant. We establish
the existence of equilibria and discuss the nature of the inefficiencies introduced by the presence of asymmetric information.
We also illustrate the properties of the model in three simple examples.
We would like to thank Alberto Bisin, Armando Dominioni, Piero Gottardi, Tito Pietra, Paolo Siconolfi, and an anonymous referee
for useful suggestions and comments. 相似文献
57.
58.
Marco BELLUCCI Luca BAGNOLI Mario BIGGERI Vittorio RINALDI 《Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics》2012,83(1):25-59
ABSTRACT: The aim of this paper is to introduce a multidimensional assessment model for organizations that have multiple goals and are not driven exclusively by profit. Therefore, it is an assessment method particularly suitable for social enterprises. In order to measure the efficiency of production units in each dimension, the Data Envelopment Analysis non‐parametric method is applied. Our case study is concerned with Fair Trade shops and members of the consortium Altromercato for which we collected variables that could be associated with input and output for the economic, socio‐cultural and organizational dimensions. The results of the analysis confirm the presence of economies of scale in the economic dimension but not in the socio‐cultural dimension. Moreover, our organizational analysis confirmed a low general professionalization. Our results also confirm, on the one hand, the more pronounced capacity of cooperatives to sell Fair Trade products compared to associations, which, on the other hand, have the tendency to achieve proportionately better results in the socio‐cultural dimension. 相似文献
59.
Why was the Chinese State able to promote economic growth during the reform era, yet has been unable to do so over the previous 30 years? In this article, we focus on a specific aspect of the question, which will contribute to the development of a more comprehensive explanation: the specific institutional arrangement that may induce the autocratic government to adopt growth‐enhancing policies. We consider a standard political‐agency model (Besley, 2006) where the incumbent leader may or may not be congruent, and where, to maintain power, both leader types need the support of the selectorate, an elite group having a say in selecting the leader, as well as associated access to special privileges. Primarily, we find that in autocracies, without electoral discipline to restrain the opportunistic behaviour of a leader, the size of the selectorate should be intermediate; if it is too small, the selectorate is captured by the leader and has no disciplinary role, but if too big, the leader's incentives are diluted. 相似文献
60.
Analyses of the effects of trade policies focus on comparisons of two different steady states, restricting the investigation to the long run. In order to account for the adjustments and to capture the relevant transmission mechanisms of changes in trade costs, such as market size, entry and exit, as well as productivity changes of firms, we base our trade policy analysis on a dynamic new trade theory model. This approach has two advantages. (i) It allows us to take account of the transitional process after a change in tariffs. (ii) It allows us to take account of the shortsightedness of policy makers. We show that Nash-equilibrium tariffs based on a dynamic trade model are lower than Nash-equilibrium tariffs based on a static model. We also show that shortsighted politicians tend to set lower tariffs than politicians with a longer planning horizon. 相似文献