全文获取类型
收费全文 | 39343篇 |
免费 | 439篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 6914篇 |
工业经济 | 2481篇 |
计划管理 | 6227篇 |
经济学 | 8996篇 |
综合类 | 1051篇 |
运输经济 | 147篇 |
旅游经济 | 316篇 |
贸易经济 | 7593篇 |
农业经济 | 1113篇 |
经济概况 | 4276篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 624篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 118篇 |
2020年 | 241篇 |
2019年 | 356篇 |
2018年 | 2600篇 |
2017年 | 2432篇 |
2016年 | 1575篇 |
2015年 | 374篇 |
2014年 | 558篇 |
2013年 | 2319篇 |
2012年 | 1007篇 |
2011年 | 2558篇 |
2010年 | 2338篇 |
2009年 | 2114篇 |
2008年 | 2083篇 |
2007年 | 2327篇 |
2006年 | 504篇 |
2005年 | 817篇 |
2004年 | 880篇 |
2003年 | 1005篇 |
2002年 | 686篇 |
2001年 | 532篇 |
2000年 | 566篇 |
1999年 | 447篇 |
1998年 | 447篇 |
1997年 | 452篇 |
1996年 | 416篇 |
1995年 | 372篇 |
1994年 | 393篇 |
1993年 | 452篇 |
1992年 | 433篇 |
1991年 | 407篇 |
1990年 | 392篇 |
1989年 | 335篇 |
1988年 | 325篇 |
1987年 | 316篇 |
1986年 | 358篇 |
1985年 | 428篇 |
1984年 | 470篇 |
1983年 | 418篇 |
1982年 | 395篇 |
1981年 | 422篇 |
1980年 | 374篇 |
1979年 | 406篇 |
1978年 | 330篇 |
1977年 | 309篇 |
1976年 | 275篇 |
1975年 | 213篇 |
1974年 | 219篇 |
1973年 | 214篇 |
1972年 | 153篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
951.
This study clarifies the types of motives that are important as a source of cooperation in a linear public goods experiment. Our experimental design separates contributions into those due to confusion, one-shot motives (which includes altruism, warm-glow, inequality aversion, and conditional cooperation), and multi-round motives (which includes a strategic motive under incomplete information, a failure of backward induction, and reciprocity). The experiment reveals that multi-round motives plays an important role in driving cooperative behavior. Confusion and one-shot motives play a minor role. 相似文献
952.
953.
We show how to obtain coherent structural-form (SF) exclusion restrictions using the reduced-form (RF) parameter ratios. It will be shown that an over-identified SF corresponds to a group of regressors sharing the same RF ratio value; those regressors should be excluded jointly from the SF. If there is no group structure, then the SF is just-identified;
in this case, however, it is no longer clear which regressor should be excluded. Hence, just-identified SF’s are more arbitrary than over-identified SF’s in terms of exclusion restrictions. This is in stark contrast to the notion that the former is less arbitrary than the latter,
because the former excludes fewer regressors. We formalize these points, and then suggest to find the number of modes in the
estimated RF ratios as a way to find groups in the ratios. For this purpose, an informal graphical method using a kernel nonparametric
method and a formal modality test are employed. An empirical example with selling price in a residential real estate market
and duration on the market as two endogenous variables is provided.
The authors are grateful to the editor and two anonymous referees for their comments 相似文献
954.
Erwan Gautier 《Empirical Economics》2008,35(2):301-332
This paper provides some new empirical findings for how French producers set prices. We used the micro data that composes
the producer and business-service price indices from 1994 to 2005. First we address how producer prices are collected. Then
we present the main characteristics of how producers change their prices: they are modified infrequently and in small amounts.
Also, a behavioural heterogeneity across sectors is observed. Business-service prices change less often than industrial producer
prices. The data corroborates both time and state-dependent model predictions. Taylor contracts are not unusual, but a firm’s
prices will also react to its economic situation. Nevertheless, the most relevant models, to explain producer price rigidity,
are time-dependent.
“The fact that some prices are rigid or sticky, while others are variable, has attracted a good deal of comments from economists in recent years” Tucker (1938)This study was conducted in the context of the Eurosystem Inflation Persistence Network. Data were processed under the responsibility of INSEE in the context of an agreement between INSEE and the Banque de France (20B-21B-E301/R05019/2005). 相似文献
955.
Using a two-regime model of the inflation-unemployment process for US data 1960:2 to 2000:2, this paper finds strong evidence
to support the Eisner puzzle, which occurs when the short-run Phillips curve (SRPC) is flatter at low rates of unemployment
than at higher rates. The puzzling aspect of this pattern is the expectation of excess demand to become apparent at very low
rates of unemployment causing the SRPC to be steep rather than fairly flat. We show the puzzle can be resolved by estimating
a three-regime model which reveals a steep SRPC at very low rates of unemployment. The estimates of the three regime model
also reveal a horizontal SRPC at intermediate rates of unemployment, implying the existence of a range of equilibrium rates
of unemployment at those intermediate rates.
相似文献
Ian M. McDonaldEmail: |
956.
Anton P. Barten 《Empirical Economics》1993,18(1):129-158
The functional form of consumer allocation models should be able to satisfy theoretical properties derived from the theory of consumer demand. The paper sketches four approaches that meet this condition. Of course, also empirical performance matters. Next to naive goodness-of-fit comparison, non-nested hypothesis testing can be employed. The latter technique is applied to a comparison of four versions of differential demand systems: the Rotterdam system, a version of the Almost Ideal Demand (AID) system, the CBS system and the NBR system. These systems are artificially nested in a more general model using scalar weights in contrast to Barten and McAleer (1991) who use matrix weights for this purpose. Annual data over the period 1921–1981 for The Netherlands for four major groups of consumer expenditure have been used for the empirical application. The CBS system dominates the others. 相似文献
957.
958.
Marek Vokoun 《Empirica》2016,43(1):111-139
This paper describes the role of R&D and analyse its impact on productivity in the Czech economy in a CDM model. Four CIS waves (2001, 2003, 2006, and 2008) were used in the CDM model. The estimated low innovation input elasticity around 9 % describes the Czechs as poor innovators in the EU. This economy was a developing country until 2006 and we have observed a substantive FDI inflow since 1998. Multinationals have a higher sales share now and are an essential part of the economy. Multinationals engage less in innovation, but innovating MNEs spend more on R&D per employee and appropriate more from their innovated goods. The FDI inflow was a form of innovation wave. Innovation output is an important determinant for boosting productivity among SME’s. Public support had positive effect on innovation intensity; however, no additional effect on innovation output. 相似文献
959.
This article examines the notion of competitive neutrality when setting access prices for vertically integrated bottleneck networks. In contrast to the claims of regulated firms (for example, Telstra), it is not possible to argue that access charges that involve unit prices in excess of short‐run marginal cost reflect competitive neutrality. That is, we demonstrate that in general models of downstream oligopoly, upstream prices that differ from marginal cost are not competitively neutral in the sense of placing integrated and non‐integrated firms on an equal basis. 相似文献
960.
The future of farming: The value of ecosystem services in conventional and organic arable land. An experimental approach 总被引:5,自引:0,他引:5
In the current work, a novel, experimental ‘bottom-up’ approach is used to quantify the economic value of ecosystem services (ES) associated with highly modified arable landscapes in Canterbury, New Zealand. First, the role of land management practices in the maintenance and enhancement of ES in agricultural land was investigated by quantifying the economic value of ES at the field level under organic and conventional arable systems. This quantification was based on an experimental approach in contrast with earlier value transfer methods. Total economic value of ES in organic fields ranged from US $1610 to US $19,420 ha− 1 yr− 1 and that of conventional fields from US $1270 to US $14,570 ha− 1 yr− 1. The non-market value of ES in organic fields ranged from US $460 to US $5240 ha− 1 yr− 1. The range of non-market values of ES in conventional fields was US $50 — 1240 ha− 1 yr− 1. There were significant differences between organic and conventional fields for the economic values of some ES. Next, this economic information was used to extrapolate and to calculate the total and non-market value of ES in Canterbury arable land. The total annual economic and non-market values of ES for the conventional arable area in Canterbury (125,000 ha) were US $332 million and US $71 million, respectively. If half the arable area under conventional farming shifted to organic practices, the total economic value of ES would be US $192 million and US $166 million annually for organic and conventional arable area, respectively. In this case, the non-market value of ES for the organic area was US $65 million and that of conventional area was US $35 million annually. This study demonstrated that arable farming provides a range of ES which can be measured using field experiments based on ecological principles by incorporating a ‘bottom-up’ approach. The work also showed that conventional New Zealand arable farming practices can severely reduce the financial contribution of some of these services in agriculture whereas organic agricultural practices enhance their economic value. 相似文献