全文获取类型
收费全文 | 201篇 |
免费 | 0篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 25篇 |
工业经济 | 5篇 |
计划管理 | 42篇 |
经济学 | 92篇 |
运输经济 | 5篇 |
旅游经济 | 2篇 |
贸易经济 | 23篇 |
农业经济 | 4篇 |
经济概况 | 3篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 1篇 |
2023年 | 2篇 |
2022年 | 5篇 |
2021年 | 5篇 |
2020年 | 3篇 |
2019年 | 14篇 |
2018年 | 8篇 |
2017年 | 6篇 |
2016年 | 6篇 |
2015年 | 3篇 |
2014年 | 11篇 |
2013年 | 26篇 |
2012年 | 15篇 |
2011年 | 9篇 |
2010年 | 15篇 |
2009年 | 16篇 |
2008年 | 8篇 |
2007年 | 5篇 |
2006年 | 2篇 |
2005年 | 3篇 |
2004年 | 3篇 |
2003年 | 3篇 |
2002年 | 7篇 |
2001年 | 4篇 |
2000年 | 5篇 |
1999年 | 3篇 |
1998年 | 2篇 |
1996年 | 2篇 |
1995年 | 1篇 |
1994年 | 2篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 1篇 |
1983年 | 1篇 |
1980年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有201条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
61.
Paola Rota 《International Economic Review》2004,45(1):25-48
We consider a dynamic model in which firms decide whether or not to vary labor in the presence of fixed costs. By exploiting the first‐order condition for optimality, we derive a semireduced form in which firms' intertemporal employment is defined by a standard marginal productivity condition augmented by a forward‐looking term. We obtain a marginal productivity equilibrium relation that takes into account the future alternatives of adjustment or nonadjustment that firms face. We use the structural parameter from this condition to estimate the fixed cost within a discrete decision process. Fixed costs are about 15 months' labor cost. 相似文献
62.
63.
64.
We study a bargaining game between an individual and an ‘alliance’ in the sense of Manzini and Mariotti (J Econ Theory 121:128–41,
2005), in which the opponent of the alliance is incompletely informed about the relative strengths of its members. The best
equilibrium outcome for the alliance under a unanimity rule is not attainable with a non-unanimity rule. However, unlike in
the complete information model, less than optimal outcomes and delays may occur with positive probability even under unanimity,
depending on the prior beliefs and the preferences of the agents.
We are grateful to a careful referee for comments. We wish to thank Clara Ponsati for useful comments. 相似文献
65.
In deregulated transport markets, a firm's ownership status and management system represent an important issue. Property right theory suggests that productivity and performance are higher in the private than in the public sector. In Switzerland, providers of bus transportation are traditionally corporations, though a large part of their equity shares are still held by the public sector (federal government, cantons, municipalities). This paper examines the potential impact of ownership on the cost of bus service provision for a sample of private, public and mixed bus companies in Switzerland. The estimation of a translog cost model has been considered for 34 bus transit companies observed over 5 years (1991–1995). The results only partially confirm that if the private sector holds shares in the company's capital, efficiency is enhanced. In addition, measures of economies of scale and density are derived and discussed within the actual public transport policy. 相似文献
66.
Jérôme Creel Paola Monperrus-Veroni Francesco Saraceno 《Scottish journal of political economy》2009,56(5):580-607
This paper uses the SVAR methodology to investigate the effects of public investment on GDP and, more specifically, the effects of the introduction of a golden rule of public finance. We extend the existing literature by estimating a model for the British economy that takes into account long-run factors such as public debt accumulation and policy interactions. We find that in such a long-run framework, public investment has a significant and permanently positive effect on GDP; this result runs counter to the most recent literature on the topic using SVAR, which was limited to a short-run specification. We further find, by comparing different subsamples, that the introduction of the golden rule in 1997 strengthened the positive effect of public investment. 相似文献
67.
In this paper, we examine the allocation of tasks between a principal and an agent considering their incentives to provide effort, their different abilities in handling tasks, and transmission costs. We focus our attention on two tasks: the first may be handled by the principal or by the agent, whereas the second is necessarily carried out by the agent. Under a fully decentralised organisation, the agent performs both tasks, whereas, under partial delegation, the principal handles the first task and transfers the outcome to the agent who handles the second task. Assuming technological complementarities, from our analysis it emerges that, if there is imperfect observability of effort, full delegation is better at eliciting effort by the agent in the second task, whereas, in comparison with partial delegation, it lowers effort in the first task. Although with contractible effort, the choice between the two organisational forms depends only on transmission costs and on the relative ability of its members, when moral hazard problems are taken into account, the organisational choice is related to the relative importance played by the two tasks in production. If the agent's task is relatively important in production, full delegation, encouraging a higher level of effort in this task, may be optimal, even if technological factors favour partial delegation. Copyright © 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 相似文献
68.
Raúl Gómez Martínez Miguel Prado Román Paola Plaza Casado 《Journal of Behavioral Finance》2019,20(2):227-238
Traditional automated trading systems use rules and filters based on Chartism to send orders to the market, aiming to beat the market and obtain positive returns in bullish or bearish contexts. However, these systems do not consider the investors’ mood that many studies have demonstrated its effects over the evolution of financial markets. The authors describe 2 \"big data\" algorithmic trading systems over Ibex 35 future. These systems send orders to the market to open long or short positions, based on an artificial intelligence model that uses investors’ mood. To measure the investors' mood, the authors use semantic analysis algorithms that qualify as good, bad, or neutral any communication related to Ibex 35 made on social media (Twitter) or news media. After 1.5 years of research, conclusions are: First, the authors observe positive returns, demonstrating that investors’ mood has predictive capacity on the evolution of the Ibex 35. Second, these systems have beaten the Ibex 35 index, showing the imperfect efficiency of the financial markets. Third, big data algorithmic trading systems numbers are better in Sharpe ratio, success rate, and profit factor than traditional trading systems on the Ibex 35, listed in the Trading Motion platform. 相似文献
69.
Individuals’ beliefs about the trustworthiness of a generic member of the population are both heterogeneous across individuals and persistent across generations. We investigate one mechanism yielding these dual patterns: false consensus. In the context of a trust game experiment, we show that the relationship between behavior and beliefs is consistent with individuals extrapolating their trust beliefs from their own trustworthiness and that this tendency continues even after substantial learning opportunities. We go on to provide evidence suggesting that one's own trustworthiness can be traced back to the values parents transmit to their children during their upbringing. 相似文献
70.
Paola Verico 《Decisions in Economics and Finance》1994,17(1):3-10
Vengono messe in luce alcune problematiche che si presentano quando si applichi il metodo della simulazione stocastica allo studio dell'evoluzione nel tempo di collettività chiuse ed unitarie esposte a più cause di eliminazione. Viene poi proposta un'impostazione che unifica i diversi punti di vista adottati in recenti lavori sull'argomento.
Summary We investigate some problems that are met when studying by stochastic simulation the evolution over time of a (closed and homogeneous) collectivity underlying to more than one cause of elimination, and propose a unifying viewpoint on the argument.相似文献