全文获取类型
收费全文 | 5003篇 |
免费 | 153篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 923篇 |
工业经济 | 420篇 |
计划管理 | 936篇 |
经济学 | 1085篇 |
综合类 | 47篇 |
运输经济 | 44篇 |
旅游经济 | 100篇 |
贸易经济 | 873篇 |
农业经济 | 204篇 |
经济概况 | 519篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
邮电经济 | 4篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 26篇 |
2021年 | 41篇 |
2020年 | 80篇 |
2019年 | 100篇 |
2018年 | 124篇 |
2017年 | 144篇 |
2016年 | 116篇 |
2015年 | 87篇 |
2014年 | 130篇 |
2013年 | 624篇 |
2012年 | 148篇 |
2011年 | 194篇 |
2010年 | 178篇 |
2009年 | 214篇 |
2008年 | 183篇 |
2007年 | 169篇 |
2006年 | 162篇 |
2005年 | 148篇 |
2004年 | 143篇 |
2003年 | 155篇 |
2002年 | 134篇 |
2001年 | 114篇 |
2000年 | 118篇 |
1999年 | 122篇 |
1998年 | 106篇 |
1997年 | 83篇 |
1996年 | 93篇 |
1995年 | 73篇 |
1994年 | 77篇 |
1993年 | 72篇 |
1992年 | 75篇 |
1991年 | 82篇 |
1990年 | 54篇 |
1989年 | 38篇 |
1988年 | 39篇 |
1987年 | 45篇 |
1986年 | 47篇 |
1985年 | 67篇 |
1984年 | 54篇 |
1983年 | 49篇 |
1982年 | 50篇 |
1981年 | 50篇 |
1980年 | 43篇 |
1979年 | 41篇 |
1978年 | 28篇 |
1977年 | 25篇 |
1976年 | 24篇 |
1975年 | 19篇 |
1974年 | 26篇 |
1973年 | 18篇 |
排序方式: 共有5156条查询结果,搜索用时 11 毫秒
991.
A number of bargaining experiments have raised the of what is fair or just may be sufficiently powerful to generate bel and systematically from the predictions of standard bargaining experiment designed to test whether the relative impact of different certain changes in the bargaining environment. 相似文献
992.
Heather M. Rozjabek Craig I. Coleman Veronica Ashton François Laliberté Paul Oyefesobi Dominique Lejeune 《Journal of medical economics》2019,22(8):751-759
Objective: To assess long-term healthcare costs related to ischemic stroke and systemic embolism (stroke/SE) and major bleeding (MB) events in patients with non-valvular atrial fibrillation (NVAF) treated with non-vitamin K antagonist oral anticoagulants (NOACs).Materials and methods: Optum’s Clinformatics Data Mart database from 1/2009–12/2016 was analyzed. Adult patients with ≥1 stroke/SE hospitalization (index date) were matched 1:1 to patients without stroke/SE (random index date), based on propensity scores. Patients with an MB event were matched to patients without MB. All patients had an NOAC dispensing overlapping index date, ≥12?months of eligibility pre-index date, and ≥1 NVAF diagnosis. The observation period spanned from the index date until the earliest date of death, switch to warfarin, end of insurance coverage, or end of data availability. Mean costs were evaluated: (1) per-patient-per-year (PPPY) and (2) at 1, 2, 3, and 4?years using Lin's method.Results: The cost differences were, respectively, $48,807 and $28,298 PPPY for NOAC users with stroke/SE (n?=?1,340) and those with MB (n?=?3,774) events compared to controls. Cost differences of patients with vs without stroke/SE were $49,876, $51,627, $57,822, and $60,691 at 1, 2, 3, and 4?years post-index, respectively (p?0.001). These cost differences were $31,292, $35,658, $44,069, and $47,022 for patients with vs without MB after 1, 2, 3, and 4?years post-index, respectively (p?0.001).Limitations: Limitations include unobserved confounders, coding and/or billing inaccuracies, limited sample sizes over longer follow-up, and the under-reporting of mortality for deaths occurring after 2011.Conclusions: The incremental healthcare costs incurred by patients with vs without stroke/SE was nearly twice as high as those of patients with vs without MB. Moreover, each additional year up to 4?years after the first event was associated with an incremental cost for patients with a stroke/SE or MB event compared to those without an event. 相似文献
993.
994.
Paul H. Rubin 《Journal of Bioeconomics》2000,2(1):9-23
Several evolutionary mechanisms have been identified in the literature that would generate altruism in humans. The most powerful (except for kin selection) and most controversial is group selection, as recently analyzed by Sober & D.S. Wilson. I do not take a stand on the issue of the existence of group selection. Instead, I examine the level of human altruism that could exist if group selection were an engine of human evolution. For the Sober & Wilson mechanism to work, groups practicing altruism must grow faster than other groups. I call altruistic behavior that would lead to faster growth efficient altruism. This often consists of cooperation in a prisoner's dilemma. ltruistic acts such as helping a temporarily hungry or injured person would qualify as efficient altruism. Efficient altruism would also require monitoring recipients to avoid shirking. Utilitarianism would be an ethical system consistent with efficient altruism, but Marxism or the Rawlsian system would not. Discussions of efficient altruism also help understand intuitions about fairness. We perceive those behaviors as fair that are consistent with efficient altruism. It is important to understand that, even if humans are selected to be altruistic, the forms of altruism that might exist must be carefully considered and ircumscribed. 相似文献
995.
Encouraging firms to develop voluntarily more comprehensive environmental management systems (EMSs) is touted as a policy
tool to augment mandatory environmental regulations. Using a unique dataset of environmental management practices of Japanese
manufacturers and controlling for self-selection bias in survey responses, we find that proxies for regulatory pressures and
consumer pressures are the most important factors that motivate firms toward more comprehensive EMSs. Despite the oft-claimed
“voluntary” nature of EMS development, our results show that the government may have a role to play in both directly and indirectly
affecting EMS development by firms.
相似文献
996.
997.
Paul Eckerstorfer Johannes Halak Jakob Kapeller Bernhard Schütz Florian Springholz Rafael Wildauer 《Review of Income and Wealth》2016,62(4):605-627
It is a well‐known criticism that if the distribution of wealth is highly concentrated, survey data are hardly reliable when it comes to analyzing the richest parts of society. This paper addresses this criticism by providing a general rationale of the underlying methodological problem as well as by proposing a specific methodological approach tailored to correcting the arising bias. We illustrate the latter approach by using Austrian data from the Household Finance and Consumption Survey. Specifically, we identify suitable parameter combinations by using a series of maximum‐likelihood estimates and appropriate goodness‐of‐fit tests to avoid arbitrariness with respect to the fitting of the Pareto distribution. Our results suggest that the alleged non‐observation bias is considerable, accounting for about one quarter of total net wealth in the case of Austria. The method developed in this paper can easily be applied to other countries where survey data on wealth are available. 相似文献
998.
This paper examines the relative impact of economic freedom, civil liberties, and political rights on growth. A system of three simultaneous equations is used to unearth the channels through which these institutional dimensions affect economic growth. These include greater efficiency and enlarged investment in physical and human capital. The sample contains 79 countries and six periods covering the years from 1976 to 2005. The results show that the three dimensions of institutional quality are important for economic growth either through a better allocation of resources or, indirectly, through the stimulation of investment in physical and human capital. 相似文献
999.
1000.
Zoning and Industrial Land Values: The Case of Philadelphia 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
This paper examines the market effects of zoning. Using the hedonic framework, we perform an empirical analysis that shows that lots zoned for industrial use in our study area are associated with a 58% price discount. The paper highlights the outcome of static zoning policies in a dynamic world. As the demand for industrial land in Philadelphia declined (resulting in vacancies), prices fell, but zoning was slow to adjust, therefore land conversion did not occur to re-equilibrate. 相似文献