全文获取类型
收费全文 | 3935篇 |
免费 | 98篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 716篇 |
工业经济 | 222篇 |
计划管理 | 615篇 |
经济学 | 848篇 |
综合类 | 43篇 |
运输经济 | 14篇 |
旅游经济 | 30篇 |
贸易经济 | 609篇 |
农业经济 | 183篇 |
经济概况 | 752篇 |
邮电经济 | 1篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 22篇 |
2021年 | 24篇 |
2020年 | 46篇 |
2019年 | 56篇 |
2018年 | 133篇 |
2017年 | 139篇 |
2016年 | 117篇 |
2015年 | 66篇 |
2014年 | 115篇 |
2013年 | 398篇 |
2012年 | 140篇 |
2011年 | 133篇 |
2010年 | 144篇 |
2009年 | 160篇 |
2008年 | 138篇 |
2007年 | 143篇 |
2006年 | 116篇 |
2005年 | 69篇 |
2004年 | 91篇 |
2003年 | 81篇 |
2002年 | 68篇 |
2001年 | 47篇 |
2000年 | 68篇 |
1999年 | 50篇 |
1998年 | 67篇 |
1997年 | 35篇 |
1996年 | 60篇 |
1995年 | 41篇 |
1994年 | 56篇 |
1993年 | 52篇 |
1992年 | 59篇 |
1991年 | 57篇 |
1990年 | 65篇 |
1989年 | 31篇 |
1988年 | 34篇 |
1987年 | 42篇 |
1986年 | 43篇 |
1985年 | 62篇 |
1984年 | 60篇 |
1983年 | 42篇 |
1982年 | 45篇 |
1981年 | 46篇 |
1980年 | 45篇 |
1979年 | 47篇 |
1978年 | 54篇 |
1977年 | 48篇 |
1976年 | 44篇 |
1975年 | 31篇 |
1974年 | 25篇 |
1969年 | 26篇 |
排序方式: 共有4033条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
51.
Regional, national, and spatially explicit scenarios of demographic and economic change based on SRES 总被引:4,自引:0,他引:4
We report here spatially explicit scenario interpretations for population and economic activity (GDP) for the time period 1990 to 2100 based on three scenarios (A2, B1, and B2) from the IPCC Special Report on Emissions Scenarios (SRES). At the highest degree of spatial detail, the scenario indicators are calculated at a 0.5 by 0.5 degree resolution. All three scenarios follow the qualitative scenario characteristics, as outlined in the original SRES scenarios. Two scenarios (B1 and B2) also follow (with minor adjustments due to scenario improvements) the original SRES quantifications at the level of 4 and 11 world regions respectively. The quantification of the original SRES A2 scenario has been revised to reflect recent changing perceptions on the demographic outlook of world population growth. In this revised “high population growth” scenario, A2r world population reaches some 12 billion by 2100 (as opposed to some 15 billion in the original SRES A2 scenario) and is characterized by a “delayed fertility transition” that is also mirrored in a delayed (economic) development catch-up, resulting in an initially stagnating and subsequently only very slow reduction in income disparities. The spatially explicit scenario interpretation proceeds via two steps. Through a combination of decomposition and optimization methods, world regional scenario results are first disaggregated to the level of 185 countries. In a subsequent second step, national results are further disaggregated to a grid cell level, taking urbanization and regional (rural–urban) income disparities explicitly into account. A distinguishing feature of the spatially explicit scenario results reported here is that both methodologies, as well as numerical assumptions underlying the “downscaling” exercise, are scenario-dependent, leading to distinctly different spatial patterns of population and economic activities across the three scenarios examined. 相似文献
52.
RONALD R. BRAEUTIGAM 《Contemporary economic policy》1990,8(2):122-141
This article examines regulatory reform and some possible consequences of reform designed to increase the role that competition plays in the interstate natural gas pipeline industry. The analysis first provides a conceptual framework for viewing the "problem of natural monopoly" as a basis for regulation. It summarizes ways in which introducing competition for a market may be possible even if competition within a market is not possible–through competitive auctions, monopolistic competition, or contestability. The analysis then relates briefly to this framework the experiences of three U.S. industries that have undergone substantial reform during recent years–airlines, motor carriers, and railroads. Finally, it compares the natural gas pipeline industry with the others examined and suggests types of regulatory reform that might succeed–and those that might not succeed–in improving resource allocation. 相似文献
53.
Grinyer and Russell's (G&R, 1992) contention that Ma and Hopkins (1988) have imposed the mutually exclusive rules of the valuation-based paradigm on the matching-based paradigm that underlies accounting practice is overly defensive and misguided. Our 1988 paper was an attempt to throw light on why there was so little agreement on the rules governing the treatment of goodwill. G&R's comment does not change our view that the only answer to the 'puzzle' lies in the lack of a full understanding of the nature of goodwill. 相似文献
54.
55.
56.
María Xosé Vázquez Rodríguez Carmelo J. León 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2004,28(2):233-249
Altruism is a type of non-use value which can have different definitions depending on the type of goods entering the utility function of the altruists and their expectations about the contributions of others. The purpose of this paper is to measure the trade-offs between different types of altruist values originating from social and environmental policies. Environmental policies are concerned with reducing health effects from a power plant while social policies involve both the attainment of public facilities for education and leisure and an increase in the income of the affected population. The empirical application utilizes a choice experiment technique which allows for valuation of multiple goods. Health effects are decomposed into the values of the risk of becoming ill, the duration of the episodes and the limitations imposed by illness. Altruist values are elicited from a population that is not affected by pollution. Results show that altruism is significant for policies directed to reducing health effects and improving the income level of the affected population, whereas there is egoism for a policy aimed at improving public facilities in the polluted suburb. The value of altruism is significantly influenced by the expectations of net benefits to be received by the affected population. 相似文献
57.
58.
59.
Minna Martikainen Jussi Nikkinen Sami Vähämaa 《The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance》2009,49(2):295-307
This paper examines whether the higher profitability and valuation of family firms is related to differences in production technologies and production efficiency. Using data on S&P 500 manufacturing firms, we find that family firms are more productive than comparable non-family firms. Furthermore, our results show that the production technologies of family and non-family firms do not differ per se, thereby suggesting that the differences in the level of production output are caused by higher production efficiency of family firms. These findings indicate that the superior performance of family firms is related to their more efficient use of labor and capital resources. 相似文献
60.
Gabriel-Eduard Vîlcu 《Applied economics letters》2018,25(2):106-110
In Appl. Econ. Lett. 18 (2011), 1777–1784, as a natural generalization of some famous production models with two inputs, C.A. Ioan and G. Ioan introduced a new class of production functions with constant return to scale, called sum production function, and proved three theorems of characterization for such production models. In this article, we give new and more simple proofs of these theorems, extending also the results to the case of increased/decreased return to scale. The generalization to the case of an arbitrary number of inputs is also discussed. 相似文献