首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   19971篇
  免费   199篇
财政金融   3114篇
工业经济   906篇
计划管理   3145篇
经济学   4791篇
综合类   494篇
运输经济   63篇
旅游经济   51篇
贸易经济   5239篇
农业经济   110篇
经济概况   1638篇
信息产业经济   44篇
邮电经济   575篇
  2024年   6篇
  2023年   83篇
  2022年   49篇
  2021年   73篇
  2020年   126篇
  2019年   125篇
  2018年   2471篇
  2017年   2284篇
  2016年   1429篇
  2015年   231篇
  2014年   263篇
  2013年   749篇
  2012年   626篇
  2011年   2044篇
  2010年   1957篇
  2009年   1637篇
  2008年   1588篇
  2007年   1905篇
  2006年   137篇
  2005年   458篇
  2004年   505篇
  2003年   604篇
  2002年   285篇
  2001年   93篇
  2000年   71篇
  1999年   20篇
  1998年   41篇
  1997年   17篇
  1996年   31篇
  1995年   9篇
  1994年   13篇
  1993年   11篇
  1992年   13篇
  1991年   10篇
  1990年   9篇
  1989年   13篇
  1988年   4篇
  1987年   4篇
  1986年   17篇
  1985年   16篇
  1984年   18篇
  1983年   9篇
  1982年   16篇
  1981年   8篇
  1980年   6篇
  1976年   4篇
  1974年   8篇
  1969年   4篇
  1889年   4篇
  1879年   3篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
71.
The impact of demand growth on the collusion possibilities is investigated in a Cournot supergame where market growth may trigger future entry and the collusive agreement is enforced by the most profitable ‘grim trigger strategies’ available. It is shown that even in situations where perfect collusion can be sustained after entry, coping with a potential entrant in a market which is growing over time may completely undermine any pre‐entry collusive plans of the incumbent firms. This is because, before entry, a deviation and the following punishment phase may become more attractive thanks to their additional effect in terms of delaying entry.  相似文献   
72.
73.
74.
75.
The general design for the real-time electricity market presented in this paper optimizes and prices both real and reactive power simultaneously in an AC setting, where all assets—generation, load and transmission—are allowed to bid and are financially settled at the locational price times energy consumed or produced. The result is that transmission lines are compensated for both capacity and admittance, providing incentives for efficient operation of transmission-related assets such as FACTS devices, if price-taking behavior is assumed. Losses are incorporated into the design and become an operating cost for transmission. The market design is shown to be revenue neutral and, under some assumptions, nonconfiscatory.   相似文献   
76.
77.
78.
We extend Condorcet’s Jury Theorem (Essai sur l’application de l’analyse à la probabilité des décisions rendues à la pluralité des voix. De l’imprimerie royale, 1785) to weighted voting games with voters of two kinds: a fixed (possibly empty) set of ‘major’ voters with fixed weights, and an ever-increasing number of ‘minor’ voters, whose total weight is also fixed, but where each individual’s weight becomes negligible. As our main result, we obtain the limiting probability that the jury will arrive at the correct decision as a function of the competence of the few major players. As in Condorcet’s result the quota q = 1/2 is found to play a prominent role. I wish to thank Maurice Koster, Moshé Machover, Guillermo Owen and two anonymous referees for helpful comments.  相似文献   
79.
Background risk can influence the performance of insurance markets that must deal with adverse selection when applicants are risk vulnerable, since they are more averse to bearing the insurable risk as a result of their exposures to background risk. We show that background risk always results in a lower deductible for the incentive constrained contract, and that a broader range of markets attains the stable sequential equilibrium cross-subsidized pair of separating contracts. We conclude that background risk always improves the performance of markets for coverage against (insurable) foreground risks that must deal with adverse selection. We also find, however, that these improvements are never sufficient to offset the cost to insureds of bearing the background risk.  相似文献   
80.
This paper presents MAcMap–HS‐6, a database providing a consistent, ad valorem equivalent measure of tariff duties and tariff rate quotas for 163 countries and 208 partners, at the six‐digit level of the Harmonized System (5111 products), accounting for all preferential agreements. We describe the methodology used to compute and aggregate an ad valorem equivalent of applied protection. Emphasis is placed on minimizing the endogeneity bias in the aggregation procedure, while acknowledging structural differences in export specialization. The resulting quantitative assessment is illustrated by giving an overview of applied protection across the world in 2001, in terms of average as well as distribution.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号