首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   189篇
  免费   2篇
财政金融   14篇
工业经济   4篇
计划管理   27篇
经济学   57篇
旅游经济   3篇
贸易经济   68篇
农业经济   1篇
经济概况   13篇
邮电经济   4篇
  2020年   1篇
  2019年   2篇
  2018年   2篇
  2017年   2篇
  2016年   3篇
  2015年   3篇
  2014年   5篇
  2013年   8篇
  2012年   8篇
  2011年   10篇
  2010年   11篇
  2009年   15篇
  2008年   12篇
  2007年   8篇
  2006年   9篇
  2005年   7篇
  2004年   1篇
  2003年   5篇
  2002年   4篇
  2001年   4篇
  2000年   6篇
  1999年   8篇
  1998年   4篇
  1997年   5篇
  1996年   2篇
  1995年   4篇
  1994年   1篇
  1993年   5篇
  1992年   4篇
  1991年   3篇
  1990年   1篇
  1989年   2篇
  1988年   2篇
  1987年   2篇
  1986年   1篇
  1984年   5篇
  1981年   2篇
  1980年   2篇
  1979年   4篇
  1978年   3篇
  1977年   1篇
  1975年   1篇
  1970年   1篇
  1969年   2篇
排序方式: 共有191条查询结果,搜索用时 31 毫秒
31.
Weaknesses of advertising self-control: The case of the “Deutscher Werberat» (German Advertising Council, DWR). The paper scrutinizes the activities of DWR, the most important self-regulatory institution of German advertising business, founded in 1972. Its ten members come from the industry, the media, and the advertising agencies and professions. Consumers are not represented on the board; there is only a committee for co-ordinating contacts with the leading German organization, namely Arbeitsgemeinschaft der Verbraucher. DWR invites complaints from everybody about indecent, misleading, and unfair advertising. The main guideline of DWR is the code of the International Chamber of Commerce, the ICC Rules. DWR has hardly any possibilities to sanction those firms that infringe the rules; it can ask for only voluntary compliance with its opinions. In order to understand how DWR really works, the author examined advertisements in different German magazines (e. g.,Stern, Der Spiegel) from June 1976 to December 1978. For about 320 of those, published by well-known German and foreign firms, he filed complaints to DWR because of alleged contravention of advertising rules. They constituted a large part of the complaints received by DWR since in total, the Council dealt with about 670 complaints during that period. 73.9% of the author's complaints were not accepted by DWR (see Table 1 of the paper). The following weak points of the self-controlling system were discovered:
  1. Complaint handling takes an extraordinary long time: an average of 32 days for complaints which were successfully filed (see Table 2). This means that a suspect advertisement can appear for quite some time before it is stopped by the opinion of DWR.
  2. There are, in the view of the author, many wrong decisions, especially in cases of misleading advertising (ambiguous, hyperbolical, incomplete, untrue claims). Fifty-two of the advertisements which had been judged acceptable by DWR could be stopped with the help of other institutions.
  3. The procedure of complaint handling gives cause for criticism, for instance, in cases of ambiguity, interpretations usually favour the advertiser. Of the complainant, DWR demands proof that an advertiser's claim is untrue, whereas the advertiser remains in the clear if he makes some vague statements to the effect that the claim is true or the complainant's arguments are incorrect.
The author concludes by making some proposals for reform of the self-regulatory system and for the increase of its efficiency. In his opinion, self-regulation does not exclude government intervention in advertising, however.  相似文献   
32.
Journal of Consumer Policy - Der Beitrag stellt einen Vorschlag über Möglichkeiten der Erweiterung der Rechtsberatung durch die Verbraucherzentralen in Richtung auf eine Erhöhung von...  相似文献   
33.
34.
This note empirically analyses how exchange rate fluctuations affects firms’ optimal production and exporting decisions. A firm’s elasticity of risk aversion determines the direction of the impact of exchange rate risk on exports. Based on a flexible utility function that incorporates all possible risk preferences, a unique structurally estimable equation is derived. Quantile regression method is used to estimate this equation and compute the risk aversion elasticities for a panel of Indian firms. This approach allows us to demonstrate how characteristics of exporters at the intensive margin varies with the level of elasticities across the conditional exchange rate distribution.  相似文献   
35.
We examine optimal production and export decisions of a firm facing exchange rate uncertainty, where the firm's management is not only risk averse but also regret averse, i.e., is characterized by a utility function that includes disutility from having chosen ex post suboptimal alternatives. Experimental and empirical results support the view that managers tend to be regret averse. Under regret aversion a negative risk premium need not preclude the firm from exporting which would be the case if the firm were only risk averse. Exporting creates an implicit hedge against the possibility of regret when the realized spot exchange rate turns out to be high. The regret‐averse firm as such has a greater ex ante incentive to export than the purely risk averse firm. Finally, we use a two‐state example to illustrate that the firm optimally exports more (less) to the foreign country than in the case of pure risk aversion if the low (high) spot exchange rate is more likely to prevail. Regret aversion as such plays a crucial role in determining the firm's optimal allocation between domestic sales and foreign exports.  相似文献   
36.
37.
Abstract Evidence on the effect of product market competition on unionized wages is mixed. In this paper we show theoretically that the result may reflect genuine heterogeneity in the response of union wages to product market conditions. For low levels of unionization, union bargaining power may actually be enhanced by market competition, as firms have more to lose when there is a strike. Using recent data from the UK, we explore interactions between the level of industry competition and unionization, and find supporting evidence for this hypothesis.  相似文献   
38.
Reducing taris and increasing consumption taxes is a standard IMF advice to countries that want to open up their economy without hurting government finances. Indeed, theoretical analysis of such a tari–tax reform shows an unambiguous increase in welfare and government revenues. The present paper examines whether the country that implements such a reform ends up opening up its markets to international trade, i.e. whether its market access improves. It is shown that this is not necessarily so. We also show that, comparing to the reform of only taris, the tari–tax reform is a less efficient proposal to follow both as far as it concerns market access and welfare.  相似文献   
39.
Editorial     
Norbert Henze  Udo Kamps 《Metrika》2013,76(3):301-301
  相似文献   
40.
In a successive Cournot oligopoly, we show the welfare effects of entry in the final goods market with no scale economies but with cost difference between the firms. If the input market is very concentrated, entry in the final goods market increases welfare. If the input market is not very concentrated, entry in the final goods market may reduce welfare if the entrant is moderately cost inefficient. Hence, entry in the final goods market is more desirable if (1) the input market is very concentrated or (2) the cost difference between the incumbents and the entrant is either very small or very large. It follows from our analysis that entry increases the profits of the incumbent final goods producers if their marginal costs are sufficiently lower than the entrant’s marginal cost.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号