首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   641篇
  免费   13篇
财政金融   113篇
工业经济   28篇
计划管理   100篇
经济学   131篇
运输经济   1篇
旅游经济   1篇
贸易经济   204篇
农业经济   19篇
经济概况   46篇
邮电经济   11篇
  2023年   2篇
  2021年   4篇
  2020年   8篇
  2019年   8篇
  2018年   16篇
  2017年   12篇
  2016年   18篇
  2015年   17篇
  2014年   17篇
  2013年   40篇
  2012年   39篇
  2011年   36篇
  2010年   30篇
  2009年   42篇
  2008年   23篇
  2007年   28篇
  2006年   22篇
  2005年   21篇
  2004年   14篇
  2003年   14篇
  2002年   14篇
  2001年   18篇
  2000年   4篇
  1999年   13篇
  1998年   11篇
  1997年   11篇
  1996年   10篇
  1995年   9篇
  1994年   6篇
  1993年   6篇
  1992年   9篇
  1991年   11篇
  1990年   7篇
  1989年   6篇
  1988年   11篇
  1987年   10篇
  1986年   7篇
  1985年   13篇
  1984年   9篇
  1983年   7篇
  1982年   12篇
  1981年   8篇
  1980年   3篇
  1979年   3篇
  1978年   4篇
  1977年   2篇
  1976年   5篇
  1974年   2篇
  1971年   2篇
  1967年   2篇
排序方式: 共有654条查询结果,搜索用时 78 毫秒
651.
652.
In light of increasing licensing, we challenge the common assumption that product development and technology licensing are substitutes. We develop a resource‐based framework, which distinguishes a firm's technological resource base and technology exploitation processes. We further combine survey, patent, and financial data of 228 medium‐sized and large industrial companies to examine the interactions of firms' product development processes and technology licensing processes in order to explain heterogeneity in new product revenues, licensing performance, and firm performance. The results underscore that product development, which indicates innovative capacity, and technology licensing, which indicates desorptive capacity, are complements rather than substitutes in integrated knowledge exploitation in medium‐sized and large firms. This complementarity is particularly pronounced in firms with an emphasis on cross‐licensing and with a strong patent portfolio. Copyright © 2012 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.  相似文献   
653.
This paper considers alternative measures of a country's trading gains, i.e., the extra income that it earns (or loses) as the result of changes in the relative prices relevant for international trade, and which makes up the difference between real gross domestic product (GDP) and real gross domestic income (GDI). Looking at both the Laspeyres and the Törnqvist aggregation, we show that the trading gains really consist of two components, a terms-of-trade effect and a real-exchange-rate effect. Nearly all national statistical agencies, receiving no firm guidance from international organizations in this matter, merely consider the first effect, which suggests that the so-called trading-gain estimates they publish are incomplete and misnamed. Even more seriously, it implies that the corresponding measures of real GDI they derive are conceptually flawed. A straightforward way to circumvent these difficulties is to use the gross domestic final expenditure price index as deflator when computing real GDI and the trading gains. Some numerical estimates for Australia are provided as an illustration. The paper also identifies the underlying linear and Translog real GDI functions for which the Laspeyres and Törnqvist terms-of-trade and real-exchange-rate effects are exact.  相似文献   
654.
We combine farm accounting data with high-resolution meteorological data, and climate scenarios to estimate climate change impacts and adaptation potentials at the farm level. To do so, we adapt the seminal model of Moore and Lobell (2014) who applied panel data econometrics to data aggregated from the farm to the regional (subnational) level. We discuss and empirically investigate the advantages and challenges of applying such models to farm-level data, including issues of endogeneity of explanatory variables, heterogeneity of farm responses to weather shocks, measurement errors in meteorological variables, and aggregation bias. Empirical investigations into these issues reveal that endogeneity due to measurement errors in temperature and precipitation variables, as well as heterogeneous responses of farms toward climate change may be problematic. Moreover, depending on how data are aggregated, results differ substantially compared to farm-level analysis. Based on data from Austria and two climate scenarios (Effective Measures and High Emission) for 2040, we estimate that the profits of farms will decline, on average, by 4.4% (Effective Measures) and 10% (High Emission). Adaptation options help to considerably ameliorate the adverse situation under both scenarios. Our results reinforce the need for mitigation and adaptation to climate change.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号