全文获取类型
收费全文 | 20715篇 |
免费 | 74篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 3493篇 |
工业经济 | 1104篇 |
计划管理 | 3171篇 |
经济学 | 4713篇 |
综合类 | 558篇 |
运输经济 | 39篇 |
旅游经济 | 75篇 |
贸易经济 | 5146篇 |
农业经济 | 189篇 |
经济概况 | 1685篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 572篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 17篇 |
2020年 | 37篇 |
2019年 | 64篇 |
2018年 | 2345篇 |
2017年 | 2105篇 |
2016年 | 1252篇 |
2015年 | 136篇 |
2014年 | 175篇 |
2013年 | 557篇 |
2012年 | 547篇 |
2011年 | 2024篇 |
2010年 | 1899篇 |
2009年 | 1615篇 |
2008年 | 1614篇 |
2007年 | 1966篇 |
2006年 | 177篇 |
2005年 | 482篇 |
2004年 | 547篇 |
2003年 | 651篇 |
2002年 | 351篇 |
2001年 | 151篇 |
2000年 | 137篇 |
1999年 | 94篇 |
1998年 | 96篇 |
1997年 | 72篇 |
1996年 | 81篇 |
1995年 | 63篇 |
1994年 | 69篇 |
1993年 | 52篇 |
1992年 | 69篇 |
1991年 | 64篇 |
1990年 | 64篇 |
1989年 | 62篇 |
1988年 | 45篇 |
1987年 | 56篇 |
1986年 | 65篇 |
1985年 | 93篇 |
1984年 | 76篇 |
1983年 | 74篇 |
1982年 | 93篇 |
1981年 | 78篇 |
1980年 | 72篇 |
1979年 | 62篇 |
1978年 | 74篇 |
1977年 | 60篇 |
1976年 | 57篇 |
1975年 | 48篇 |
1974年 | 43篇 |
1973年 | 37篇 |
1971年 | 21篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
991.
This paper provides some of the first empirical evidence on labour market adjustments to exchange rate movements in Canadian
manufacturing industries. Controlling for endogeneity using generalized method of moments estimation, it is found that during
the 1981–1997 period, exchange movements have a substantial impact on labour input and that this impact has grown over time
as the manufacturing industries have become more exposed to trade. In contrast, the exchange rate effect on real wages is
estimated to be virtually zero for all manufacturing industries.
相似文献
Terence YuenEmail: |
992.
This paper presents a model to explain the official discount rate of the Central Bank of Austria–Hungary from 1876 to 1913.
The discount rate is assumed to depend on the liquidity ratio of the Bank, defined as the ratio of its stock of metals to
banknotes issued, and on changes in foreign discount rates. The paper also presents an equation explaining the liquidity ratio.
We use “not equally spaced chronologically ordered data” referring to the 50 discount rate changes enacted. The regressions
confirm that the liquidity ratio was the main determinant of the discount rate and that Germany (and not Great Britain) played
a significant role in determining the Austro–Hungarian discount rate and the liquidity ratios, supporting the view that the
classical gold standard was a decentralized multipolar system rather than a system fully dominated by London as suggested
by Keynes. The regressions also suggest that, although Austria–Hungary had an inconvertible paper currency (1879–1892) and
fluctuating exchange rates (1876–1895) and formally joined the gold standard only in 1902, it “shadowed” the behaviour of
gold standard Central Banks with such consistency that the stability of the estimated regressions was relatively unaffected
by the frequent institutional changes.
相似文献
Jürgen WoltersEmail: |
993.
In their seminal paper, Morris and Shin (Amer Econ Rev 92(5): 1521–1534, 2002a) argued that increasing the precision of public information is not always beneficial to social welfare. Svensson (Amer Econ
Rev 96: 448–451, 2006) however has disputed this by saying that although feasible, the conditions for which this was true, were not all that likely.
In that respect, therefore, increasing ‘transparency’ remains most of the times beneficial to social welfare. In this paper,
we extend the Morris and Shin attempt by setting it up as an explicit interactive game between the Central Bank, the objectives
of which we model explicitly, and the private sector. We show that in the absence of costs, both players benefit from transparency
in the manner described previously in the literature, and point the differences in their gains. Following that, we then introduce
the fact that increasing transparency comes at some costs and show how both players face incentives to free ride on each other
as a result. The presence of costs thus alters the way in which greater transparency is attained.
相似文献
Marco HoeberichtsEmail: |
994.
995.
996.
Clémence Berson 《De Economist》2018,166(4):455-476
The French labor market is segmented between permanent and temporary workers. The second category has difficulty in getting an open-ended contract. This paper aims at depicting workers on short-term contracts and shows the consequences on their professional career are negative and significant. A large part of the wage gap between permanent and temporary workers remains unexplained by observable characteristics. They receive less on-the-job training and their likelihood of obtaining a stable job is lower than 30% after 1 year and a half. They have also a higher probability of being the adjustment variable in case of an economic negative shock. These different findings show the importance of using public policies to encourage transitions from fixed-term to permanent employment and reducing labor-market duality. 相似文献
997.
Florentino Felgueroso José-Ignacio García-Pérez Marcel Jansen David Troncoso-Ponce 《De Economist》2018,166(4):503-534
Until the outbreak of the recent economic and financial crisis, Spain was leading the ranking of countries with the largest share of temporary employees. During the crisis this share has fallen to its lowest level in decades, but this does not mean that working conditions in Spain have improved. The flow of new temporary contracts is larger than ever before. A particularly striking feature is the steep growth in the volume of fixed-duration contracts lasting less than a week or a month. We document these trends and analyse how this phenomenon has affected the transition from temporary to permanent employment. 相似文献
998.
The diffusion of a novel taxing scheme (among Dutch municipalities over the period 1998–2005) is studied in which the waste disposal tax is increasing in the amount of waste a household produces. Inspection of the rise and spread of this tax shows that it is contagious: the probability of introduction is increasing in the number of neighboring municipalities that have already introduced this taxing scheme. A possible rationale is that the tax encourages the dumping of waste in neighboring municipalities. These municipalities may then introduce a similar tax to prevent dumping (spillover effect). Using panel data and a recently developed spatial probit approach (Elhorst et al. in J Appl Econom 32:422–439, 2017), it is possible to distinguish this spillover effect from time-specific effects. The results indicate the presence of strong spillovers. 相似文献
999.
1000.
We investigate the impact of supply and demand shocks in the global crude oil market on the CDX spread, in the context of a structural VAR model based on monthly data, over the period from November 2003 to October 2015. We find that the reaction of the CDX spread to changes in the real price of crude oil differs considerably depending on the sources of shocks. In the long run, crude oil supply shocks, aggregate demand shocks, and oil-specific demand shocks together account for nearly 90% of the variation of the CDX spread. 相似文献