首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   315篇
  免费   9篇
财政金融   50篇
工业经济   28篇
计划管理   48篇
经济学   75篇
综合类   6篇
运输经济   3篇
贸易经济   73篇
农业经济   10篇
经济概况   31篇
  2023年   3篇
  2020年   2篇
  2018年   8篇
  2017年   5篇
  2016年   5篇
  2015年   11篇
  2014年   10篇
  2013年   42篇
  2012年   8篇
  2011年   10篇
  2010年   11篇
  2009年   10篇
  2008年   10篇
  2007年   8篇
  2006年   11篇
  2005年   3篇
  2004年   3篇
  2003年   8篇
  2002年   11篇
  2001年   4篇
  2000年   6篇
  1999年   10篇
  1998年   4篇
  1997年   7篇
  1996年   8篇
  1995年   10篇
  1994年   10篇
  1993年   7篇
  1992年   5篇
  1991年   7篇
  1990年   4篇
  1989年   4篇
  1988年   3篇
  1987年   2篇
  1986年   4篇
  1985年   9篇
  1984年   5篇
  1983年   2篇
  1981年   2篇
  1980年   4篇
  1978年   3篇
  1975年   4篇
  1974年   2篇
  1970年   2篇
  1964年   2篇
  1960年   1篇
  1956年   1篇
  1955年   1篇
  1954年   3篇
  1952年   1篇
排序方式: 共有324条查询结果,搜索用时 562 毫秒
241.
This article compares the predictions of finite-shareholdermodels of conditional and unconditional takeover offers withthe outcomes of laboratory experiments. In addition to differentiatingbetween types of offers, the experimental designs span smalland large firms as well as different levels of offer premiums.It is found that in unconditional offers to large groups ofsubjects (28-40), the symmetric Nash equilibrium predicts observedtendering frequencies quite accurately. For other experimentaldesigns, the results are mixed. The analysis of shareholdertendering strategies from the experiment yields insights into(I) the effects of takeover offer designs, (ii) the appropriatenessof finite-shareholder models for research, and (iii) the costsof free riding when shareholders are nonatomistic.  相似文献   
242.
In 1981 the WHO approved a code of practice for the marketing of breastmilk substitutes, and in 1983 the UK Government sponsored the introduction by the manufacturers of a code which applied the WHO Code to the UK. The government used a drafting by sellers method which is almost identical to the procedure used by the Office of Fair Trading to draft the codes it sponsors. The text of the UK Code diverges from that of the WHO Code so that the present marketing mix for infant formula in the UK is protected: advertisements in the Health Service, informational materials for mothers, free samples for mothers, donations to Health Staff, an advisory service directly to mothers, and point of sale promotion. In effect, the UK Code renders the WHO Code inoperative in the UK.The comparison of the two codes suggests that the drafting by sellers procedure used for OFT-sponsored codes and adopted by the government for the UK Code of Practice for Infant Formula, results in codes that are weak ones from the point of view of the consumer. The drafting procedure eases the introduction of codes but also conserves the status quo in the market. The procedure precludes a balanced judgement between the interests of the consumers and the producers.
Ein Vergleich der internationalen und der englischen Richtlinien für das Marketing von Muttermilch-Ersatzprodukten
Zusammenfassung Im Jahre 1981 erließ die Weltgesundheitsorganisation internationale Richtlinien für das Marketing von Muttermilch-Ersatzprodukten. Zwei Jahre später unterstützte die britische Regierung die Einführung entsprechender nationaler Richtlinien für das eigene Land. Wie bei anderen britischen Marketing-Richtlinien wurden sie auch hier von den Herstellern selbst formuliert.Der Text der britischen Richtlinien weicht von den internationalen Richtlinien dahingehend ab, daß das derzeitige Marketing-Mix für Säuglingsnahrung in Großbritannien geschützt wird, nämlich Werbung im Gesundheitsdienst, Informationsmaterial für Mütter, Probepackungen für Mütter, Werbegeschenke an das Krankenhauspersonal, ein Direktberatungsdienst für Mütter sowie Verkaufsförderung in den Geschäften. Im Ergebnis werden damit die internationalen Richtlinien für Großbritannien außer Kraft gesetzt. Der Vergleich der beiden Richtlinien führt zu der Schlußfolgerung, daß die starke Beteiligung der Hersteller bei der Erarbeitung der Richtlinien, so wie sie in Großbritannien üblich ist, zu Richtlinien führt, die unter dem Gesichtspunkt des Verbraucherinteresses zu schwach sind. Das Verfahren erleichtert zwar die Einführung von Richtlinien, sichert aber zugleich den Status quo auf dem einzelnen Markt. Es verhindert dadurch einen angemessenen Ausgleich zwischen den Interessen der Nachfrager und Anbieter.


Robert Hamilton is a Lecturer in Marketing at the University of Lancaster, Gillow House, University of Lancaster, Bailrigg, Lancaster, UK, LA1 4YX, and Dale Whinnett a Research Assistant at the Trent Business School, Nottingham, UK, NG1 4B4.  相似文献   
243.
Salespeople have a moral obligation to prospect/customer, company and self. As such, they continually encounter truth-telling dilemmas. "lgnorance" and "conflict" often block the path to morally correct sales behaviors. Academics and practitioners agree that adoption of ethical codes is the most effective measure for encouraging ethical sales behaviors. Yet no ethical code has been offered which can be conveniently used to overcome the unique circumstances that contribute to the moral dilemmas often encountered in personal selling. An ethical code is developed that charts ethical paths across a variety of sales settings (addressing "ignorance") while illustrating why the cost associated with acting morally is generally reasonable (addressing "conflict"). The code applies the universal transactional notions of customer expectations and salesperson reputation to illustrate why and when salespeople are morally required to tell the truth. In doing so, the code tackles head-on the vexing question of how best to juggle mixed motives - involving self-interests, corporate-concerns, cus-tomer-needs and other influences such as the nature of the transaction. The issue of how mixed motives can be dealt with through moral means is one that ethicists have previously sidestepped (Stark, 1993).  相似文献   
244.
Voluntary export restraints have been a popular resort of industrialcountries faced with increasing competition from exports ofdeveloping countries. As a strategy for circumventing the rulesof the GATT (whose regulations preclude increases in tariffs),these nontariff barriers have been rather successful; whetherthey have been as successful in their aim of protecting andstimulating the industry concerned is another matter. This article looks at what happened when industrial countriesimposed—and then removed—voluntary export restraintson the footwear industry during the 1970s and 1980s. Why didprotectionism spread so fast and then dissipate almost as rapidly,and what effects did this coming and going have on the exportingcountries We suggest that industrial countries removed the restraintsbecause they found ?them either superfluous (the expected employmenteffect failed to materialize) or ineffective (the principalexporters maintained their market share during the height ofthe restrictions), or else because the industry was able toadjust by importing footwear at a profit. Predicting the effect of VERs, and determining how best to managethem, are critical questions for developing countries strugglingto improve their export performance in the 1990s. The resultsof detailed study of a representative industry, summarized here,may assist in the prediction and determination.   相似文献   
245.
Investing exhaustible resource rents and the path of consumption   总被引:6,自引:0,他引:6  
Abstract.  We set out dollar‐valued net national product for an economy with a wasting essential stock (oil deposit). We take up 'maintaining capital intact' and locally unchanging consumption. The percentage change in 'net investment' or 'genuine savings,' relative to the market rate of interest, denotes whether current consumption is rising, constant, or declining. JEL classification: O13, Q28, F0  相似文献   
246.
This paper estimates the contributions of differential fecundity, social heterogeneity, assortative matching and search frictions to aggregate marriage behavior in 18th century Quebec. The reduced form estimates show that a simple random matching model of the marriage market, in which there are gains to assortative matching and women may leave the marriage market at a higher rate than men, can explain these data. The estimates also show that the marriage market was segmented by social status.  相似文献   
247.
How much produced capital would resource-abundant countries have today if they had actually followed the Hartwick Rule (invest resource rents in other assets) over the last 30 years? We employ time series data on investment and rents on exhaustible resource extraction for 70 countries to answer this question. The results are striking: Venezuela, Trinidad and Tobago, and Gabon would all have as much produced capital as South Korea, while Nigeria would have five times its current level. A specific rule for sustainability – maintain positive constant genuine investment – is shown to lead to unbounded consumption.  相似文献   
248.
This paper sets forth a procedure for calculating the annual efficiency gains from alternative changes in existing international immigration restrictions and evaluates the impact of wage rate changes on nonmigrating labor. Data on US gross national product (GNP)/capita across countries are used to infer differences in the marginal productivity both between countries and across major world trading areas. The method assumes that the worldwide labor supply is fixed, that full employment occurs in all regions, and that differences in labor's marginal product across regions arise because of barriers to inward mobility of labor in high-wage countries. When these barriers are removed, labor is assumed to be reallocated and efficiency gains occur. Results of the calculations suggest large gains from the removal of global immigration controls which, in most cases, exceed existing worldwide GNP generated in the presence of labor mobility restrictions. A large portion of the gain is accounted for by labor migration between the aggregated rich and poor countries. Over 40% of the total potential gain is realized when only 10% of the wage differential is eliminated, suggesting that small changes in global migration restrictions have large marginal effects. Wage rates increase in labor-losing regions and decline in labor-receiving regions, dramatizing the incentives for labor unions in high-wage countries to oppose liberalization of immigration restrictions. These results suggest large potential worldwide efficiency gains from a move toward an international labor market free of immigration controls. This issue may be far more important to the North-South debate than a focus on initiatives such as commodity price stabilization, relaxation of trade protection, or increased aid flows.  相似文献   
249.
250.
Many brands build market share by acting as a substitute when competitive brands become undesirable or difficult to obtain. Notably, prior research offers competing strategic recommendations for marketers hoping to encourage consumers to engage in substitution. Past research examining substitute selection—measuring consumers’ beliefs about how well one product will substitute for another—suggests that marketers should offer replacements that are similar to the initially preferred product. In contrast, research examining substitute effectiveness—the consequences of substitution—suggests that differentiated brands will enjoy more long-term success. We integrate these two streams of research, explaining why there is a mismatch between substitute selection and substitute effectiveness, replicating and showing boundary conditions for the effects, and testing a managerial intervention that encourages consumers to choose more dissimilar (and more effective) substitutes.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号