首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   41101篇
  免费   843篇
  国内免费   1篇
财政金融   7497篇
工业经济   3155篇
计划管理   6970篇
经济学   9134篇
综合类   467篇
运输经济   303篇
旅游经济   682篇
贸易经济   6494篇
农业经济   1997篇
经济概况   5168篇
信息产业经济   2篇
邮电经济   76篇
  2021年   247篇
  2020年   417篇
  2019年   551篇
  2018年   726篇
  2017年   748篇
  2016年   716篇
  2015年   527篇
  2014年   806篇
  2013年   3950篇
  2012年   1124篇
  2011年   1228篇
  2010年   1009篇
  2009年   1187篇
  2008年   1155篇
  2007年   1122篇
  2006年   1007篇
  2005年   897篇
  2004年   900篇
  2003年   878篇
  2002年   863篇
  2001年   829篇
  2000年   859篇
  1999年   729篇
  1998年   751篇
  1997年   717篇
  1996年   719篇
  1995年   634篇
  1994年   691篇
  1993年   687篇
  1992年   695篇
  1991年   713篇
  1990年   619篇
  1989年   519篇
  1988年   535篇
  1987年   556篇
  1986年   570篇
  1985年   800篇
  1984年   797篇
  1983年   772篇
  1982年   729篇
  1981年   664篇
  1980年   639篇
  1979年   651篇
  1978年   515篇
  1977年   464篇
  1976年   359篇
  1975年   382篇
  1974年   329篇
  1973年   321篇
  1972年   257篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
41.
42.
Voss  Kevin E.  Gammoh  Bashar S. 《Marketing Letters》2004,15(2-3):147-159
Several papers have been published demonstrating the positive effects a single, reputable ally has on evaluations of a focal brand. Interestingly, little research has been published examining the effects of multiple brand allies. We examine the effect of an alliance with two, one, or zero well-known brand allies on evaluations of a previously unknown focal brand. The presence of a single brand ally significantly increased perceived quality and hedonic and utilitarian attitudes. While multiple alliances improved focal brand evaluations relative to the no ally condition, the second ally did not increase evaluations relative to the single ally condition.  相似文献   
43.
44.
The notion that prices impound a wide array of information, including market expectations, has led to earnings forecast models conditioned on prices. Yet, presumably, analysts' forecasts capture both public information and certain private information not previously impounded in prices. Accordingly, price-based models are seemingly an inefficient, and less effective, source of expecta-tions. This article investigates this hypothesis using financial analysts', price-based, and naive forecasts. Results indicate that analysts' forecasts (1) are at least as accurate as price-based and naive models, and (2) yield better expectations for market tests relating returns and earnings. These inferences are robust across different information environments. The evidence suggests that analysts either possess private information or are more effective information processors, or both.  相似文献   
45.
Cost of equity estimates are compared for three pricing models: the traditional local CAPM, the single (market) factor global CAPM, and the two‐factor global CAPM, with both market and currency index factors. For 2989 US stocks, the average difference in the cost of equity estimates is about 48 basis points between the local CAPM and the single‐factor global CAPM, and is about 61 basis points between the two global models. For 70 developed‐market ADRs, the corresponding average differences are 76 and 47 basis points, respectively. For 48 emerging‐market ADRs, the corresponding average differences are 57 and 70 basis points.  相似文献   
46.
In this paper we investigate the use of the structured full rank model for hedging the balance sheet of a financial institution. Simulation results suggest that the optimal hedge is insensitive to changes in parameter estimates. In addition, we hedge a portfolio of Treasury bills using both the full information covariance matrix and the structured covariance matrix. We then contrast these results with those obtained from a duration-based model. Empirical results suggest that the structured full rank model is generally more effective in hedging applications than either the full information model or duration-based model.  相似文献   
47.
48.
49.
An interest charge is made up of an award for waiting known as the real rate of interest, a premium for risk and compensation for transaction costs. Where inflation exists the lender seeks further compensation. In order to understand the composition and evolution of different versions of the usury prohibition it is necessary to ask which components of an interest charge are prohibited by each version. The Judaic prohibition has two aspects which are of particular interest to business historians and students of usury. First, the general rule is that a reward for waiting is prohibited. This focuses on the time-based part of interest charge. Second, interest is prohibited because it amounts to placing a stumbling block before the blind. This focuses on the typical gullibility of the borrower confronted by a more expert, better funded lender. Economics confirms and enriches our understanding of these important aspects of the prohibition. They achieve this by increasing our understanding of two facts: first, that the borrower is a gullible individual subject to irrational and inconsistent behaviour; and, second, that this behaviour relates to the waiting aspect of interest which is proscribed in the prohibition. How far these insights apply to other civilisations' prohibition, particularly those which derive from the Judaic prohibition, merits further study; so also do the ethical lessons of the Mosaic rules for a globalised society based on capitalism.  相似文献   
50.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号