全文获取类型
收费全文 | 163篇 |
免费 | 5篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 15篇 |
工业经济 | 10篇 |
计划管理 | 34篇 |
经济学 | 42篇 |
贸易经济 | 47篇 |
农业经济 | 4篇 |
经济概况 | 7篇 |
邮电经济 | 9篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 3篇 |
2023年 | 1篇 |
2022年 | 1篇 |
2020年 | 5篇 |
2019年 | 7篇 |
2018年 | 9篇 |
2017年 | 10篇 |
2016年 | 8篇 |
2015年 | 11篇 |
2014年 | 7篇 |
2013年 | 18篇 |
2012年 | 11篇 |
2011年 | 11篇 |
2010年 | 9篇 |
2009年 | 9篇 |
2008年 | 12篇 |
2007年 | 7篇 |
2006年 | 3篇 |
2005年 | 1篇 |
2004年 | 1篇 |
2003年 | 4篇 |
2001年 | 5篇 |
2000年 | 3篇 |
1999年 | 2篇 |
1998年 | 1篇 |
1997年 | 3篇 |
1995年 | 3篇 |
1994年 | 1篇 |
1976年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有168条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
111.
This article describes a joint project conducted from 1991 until 1993 by the Japanese National Institute of Science and Technology Policy (NISTEP) and the German Fraunhofer institute for Systems and Innovation Research (ISI). Some first outcomes, and different alternatives on how to use the data for trend interpretation and priority setting, are described.
The Japanese Delphi survey is conducted every five years and was first undertaken in 1971. In 1992, NISTEP and ISI agreed on a joint project. About 3000 Japanese experts were asked to answer more than 1000 questions based on 16 different technological areas. With financial aid from the Federal German Ministry of Research and Technology (BMFT) the Japanese fifth Delphi survey was replicated in Germany. The Japanese questions were translated and more than 1000 German experts responded to the questionnaires and judged the possible technological development within the next 20 to 30 years. The aim of this joint project is to compare the Japanese and the German answers in order to analyse possible differences and to understand the cultural influences on technology assessment. 相似文献
The Japanese Delphi survey is conducted every five years and was first undertaken in 1971. In 1992, NISTEP and ISI agreed on a joint project. About 3000 Japanese experts were asked to answer more than 1000 questions based on 16 different technological areas. With financial aid from the Federal German Ministry of Research and Technology (BMFT) the Japanese fifth Delphi survey was replicated in Germany. The Japanese questions were translated and more than 1000 German experts responded to the questionnaires and judged the possible technological development within the next 20 to 30 years. The aim of this joint project is to compare the Japanese and the German answers in order to analyse possible differences and to understand the cultural influences on technology assessment. 相似文献
112.
113.
Martin Abraham Cornelia Niessen Claus Schnabel Kerstin Lorek Veronika Grimm Kathrin Mslein Matthias Wrede 《Human Resource Management Journal》2019,29(4):657-675
Organisations increasingly adopt tracking technologies that allow managers to continuously collect highly detailed records of employee, performance, and health. On the basis of the theory of planned behaviour, we aim to identify attitudes, functions of monitoring, and control perceptions that should strengthen or lower employees' acceptance of these technologies. Our experimental vignette study among 800 respondents in Germany reveals that acceptance is more likely if employees have positive attitudes towards surveillance in general and towards monitoring in private life and if the technologies enhance labour productivity. The tendency to reject the technology increases if it is to be used for monitoring health and performance. The results indicate that these new technologies will not be accepted unconditionally and may be subject to bargaining and conflicts. In the implementation process, human resources departments will have to take account of employee interests and well‐being, which in turn may improve acceptance and performance. 相似文献
114.
115.
Nesar Ahmed Kerstin K. Zander Stephen T. Garnett 《The Australian journal of agricultural and resource economics》2011,55(2):199-219
In spite of the potential for rice‐fish farming in Bangladesh, it has been adopted by relatively few farmers because of socioeconomic, environmental, technological and institutional constraints. Rice monoculture remains the main farming system in Bangladesh even though integrated rice‐fish farming is the best farming system in terms of resource utilisation, diversity, productivity, production efficiency and food supply. Only a small number of farmers involve in integrated rice‐fish farming. This study concludes that rice‐fish farming is as production efficient as rice monoculture and that integrated performs better in terms of cost and technical efficiency compared with alternate rice‐fish farming. Integrated rice‐fish farming can help Bangladesh keep pace with the current demand for food through rice and fish production. However, a lack of technical knowledge of farmers, high production costs and risks associated with flood and drought are inhibiting more widespread adoption of the practice. 相似文献
116.
Nguyen Thang Dao Kerstin Burghaus Ottmar Edenhofer 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2017,68(1):129-173
We consider, in an overlapping generations model with an environmental externality, a scheme of contracts between any two successive generations. Under each contract, agents of the young generation invest a share of their labor income in pollution mitigation in exchange for a transfer in the second period of their lives. The transfer is financed in a pay-as-you-go manner by the next young generation. Different from previous work we assume that the transfer is granted as a subsidy to capital income rather than lump sum. We show that the existence of a contract which is Pareto improving over the situation without contract for any two generations requires a sufficiently high level of income. In a steady state with social contracts in each period, the pollution stock is lower compared to a steady state without contracts. Analytical and numerical analysis of the dynamics under Nash bargaining suggests that under reasonable conditions, also steady state income and welfare are higher. Delaying the implementation of a social contract for too long or imposing a contract with too low mitigation can be costly: Net income may inevitably fall below the threshold in finite time so that Pareto improving mitigation is no longer possible and the economy converges to a steady state with high pollution stock and low income and welfare. In the second part of the paper, we study a game theoretic setup, taking into account that credibly committing to a contract might not be possible. We show that with transfers granted as a subsidy to capital income, there exist mitigation transfer schemes which are both Pareto improving and give no generation an incentive to deviate from any of its contracts even in a dynamically efficient economy. Social contracts coexist with private savings. 相似文献
117.
Prof. Dr. Kerstin Pull ist Inhaberin des Lehrstuhls für Allgemeine Betriebswirtschaftslehre insbesondere Personal und
Organisation an der Universit?t Tübingen. 《Wirtschaftsdienst》2005,85(10):638-645
Die strikten Regulierungen im deutschen Arbeitsrecht gelten als Nachteil für Deutschland im internationalen Wettbewerb um
Produktionsstandorte. Welche Bedeutung haben arbeitsrechtliche Faktoren bei der Standortentscheidung von Unternehmen? Wie
bewerten US-Investoren das deutsche Arbeitsrecht im Vergleich? 相似文献
118.
119.
Kerstin Protz 《Heilberufe》2010,62(7):33-36
N?hrstoffbedarf sichern - Eine ausgewogene Ern?hrung sichert nicht nur die N?hrstoffzufuhr, sie sorgt auch für den reibungslosen Ablauf aller Stoffwechselprozesse. Die N?hrstoffversorgung spielt daher auch bei der Entstehung und Heilung von Wunden eine wichtige Rolle. 相似文献
120.