全文获取类型
收费全文 | 732篇 |
免费 | 15篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 102篇 |
工业经济 | 53篇 |
计划管理 | 138篇 |
经济学 | 170篇 |
综合类 | 11篇 |
运输经济 | 12篇 |
旅游经济 | 23篇 |
贸易经济 | 114篇 |
农业经济 | 37篇 |
经济概况 | 86篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 5篇 |
2021年 | 8篇 |
2020年 | 10篇 |
2019年 | 11篇 |
2018年 | 23篇 |
2017年 | 22篇 |
2016年 | 26篇 |
2015年 | 13篇 |
2014年 | 19篇 |
2013年 | 100篇 |
2012年 | 21篇 |
2011年 | 22篇 |
2010年 | 17篇 |
2009年 | 31篇 |
2008年 | 20篇 |
2007年 | 28篇 |
2006年 | 24篇 |
2005年 | 17篇 |
2004年 | 21篇 |
2003年 | 22篇 |
2002年 | 25篇 |
2001年 | 18篇 |
2000年 | 19篇 |
1999年 | 15篇 |
1998年 | 15篇 |
1997年 | 14篇 |
1996年 | 21篇 |
1995年 | 8篇 |
1994年 | 4篇 |
1993年 | 11篇 |
1992年 | 10篇 |
1991年 | 8篇 |
1990年 | 9篇 |
1989年 | 8篇 |
1988年 | 7篇 |
1987年 | 7篇 |
1986年 | 11篇 |
1985年 | 8篇 |
1984年 | 11篇 |
1983年 | 10篇 |
1982年 | 7篇 |
1981年 | 8篇 |
1980年 | 6篇 |
1979年 | 6篇 |
1976年 | 3篇 |
1975年 | 3篇 |
1974年 | 3篇 |
1973年 | 3篇 |
1972年 | 2篇 |
1971年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有747条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
111.
112.
James J. Hughes 《Industrial Relations Journal》1971,2(3):49-55
The author argues that an incomes policy with an element of enforced saving could be an effective way of combating cost inflation 相似文献
113.
114.
Nick R. Smith 《Journal of Agrarian Change》2019,19(2):249-269
This paper investigates the implementation of “one village, one product” (OVOP) in four peri‐urban villages in China's Yangtze River Delta. China's agricultural transformation, including the introduction of new corporate actors and the growing pressure of market discipline, has challenged the relevance of villages in the organization of agricultural production. In response, village cadres in thousands of Chinese villages have used OVOP to transform their villages into agro‐industrial firms and re‐exert their control over the agricultural surplus, echoing earlier examples of village corporatism. Rooted in agricultural specialization, OVOP encompasses a diversity of strategies for the production of locality‐based value. I disaggregate these strategies into four sociospatial dimensions that comprise locality—place, network, territory, and scale. Place‐based branding is the dominant strategy, but village cadres also pursue complementary sociospatial strategies to ensure their control over the realization of the brand's value and reconstitute their redistributive and administrative powers. 相似文献
115.
Accounting for Negative,Zero and Positive Willingness to Pay for Landscape Change in a National Park
Nick Hanley Sergio Colombo Bengt Kriström Fiona Watson 《Journal of Agricultural Economics》2009,60(1):1-16
In contingent valuation, despite the fact that many externalities manifest themselves as costs to some and benefits to others, most studies restrict willingness to pay to being non‐negative. In this paper, we investigate the impact of allowing for negative, zero and positive preferences for prospective changes in woodland cover in two UK national parks, the Lake District and the Trossachs. An extended spike model is used to accomplish this. The policy implications of not allowing for negative values in terms of aggregate benefits are also investigated, by comparing the extended spike model with a simple spike making use of only zero and positive bids, and a model which considers positive bids only. We find that ignoring negative values over‐states the aggregate benefits of a woodland planting project by up to 44%. 相似文献
116.
Nick Hanley Douglas MacMillan Robert E. Wright Craig Bullock Ian Simpson Dave Parsisson Bob Crabtree 《Journal of Agricultural Economics》1998,49(1):1-15
This paper reports results from a study of the economic value of the conservation benefits of Environmentally Sensitive Areas (ESAs) in Scotland. The main novelty of the approach taken is in comparing two direct valuation methods, namely contingent valuation and choice experiments, to value these benefits. The Contingent Valuation Method (CVM) is well-established as a technique for valuing the sorts of landscape and wildlife enhancements associated with ESAs. The CVM experiment reported here uses a dichotomous choice format, and includes a new correction for part-whole bias. Choice experiments are much less used as an environmental valuation technique. We note several advantages of such experiments over CVM, and then report characteristic values and ‘programme values’ estimated using the method. This application brings to light some problems in applying the choice experiment method. Finally, we discuss the issue of benefits transfer in the context of these two approaches to valuation. 相似文献
117.
Colin Haslam Nick Tsitsianis Glen Lehman Tord Andersson John Malamatenios 《Accounting Forum》2018,42(1):119-129
This article accounts for carbon emissions in the S&P 500 and explores the extent to which capital is at risk from decarbonising value chains. At a global level it is proving difficult to decouple carbon emissions from GDP growth. Top-down legal and regulatory arrangements envisaged by the Kyoto Protocol are practically redundant given inconsistent political commitment to mitigating global climate change and promoting sustainability. The United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) and European Commission (EC) are promoting the role of financial markets and financial institutions as drivers of behavioural change mobilising capital allocations to decarbonise corporate activity. 相似文献
118.
In contrast with current thinking that conglomerates are inefficient, this article begins by presenting arguments in favor of the size and structure of the large integrated oil companies, also known as "the supermajors." Among the advantages are tax efficiency, information flow, political and technological know-how, broad supplier and customer relationships, scale economies, cross-business economies of scope, brand power, and the ability to coordinate strategic initiatives across businesses. These advantages all translate into a lower cost of capital.
One problem, however, is that this lower cost of capital does not seem to be reflected in the target returns on capital currently set by the supermajors. Observing that the financial goal of a corporation is to maximize not its return on capital but rather the net present value of expected future cash flows and earnings, the authors argue that the majors need to make two major changes to current practice. First, their investment hurdle rates should be reduced from their current level of 14–15% to the weighted average cost of capital, which is estimated to run about 8–9%. Second, the actual returns on capital reported in published accounts are largely meaningless; and when evaluating new investments and existing operations alike, the companies must find an annual performance measure that better reflects the economic realities of the business. This paper recommends use of a performance measurement framework based on economic profit that should serve two critical purposes: it will encourage managers to undertake all value-increasing projects (not just those that will maintain or increase reported return on capital), and it will help the companies communicate their strategy and results to the investment community. 相似文献
One problem, however, is that this lower cost of capital does not seem to be reflected in the target returns on capital currently set by the supermajors. Observing that the financial goal of a corporation is to maximize not its return on capital but rather the net present value of expected future cash flows and earnings, the authors argue that the majors need to make two major changes to current practice. First, their investment hurdle rates should be reduced from their current level of 14–15% to the weighted average cost of capital, which is estimated to run about 8–9%. Second, the actual returns on capital reported in published accounts are largely meaningless; and when evaluating new investments and existing operations alike, the companies must find an annual performance measure that better reflects the economic realities of the business. This paper recommends use of a performance measurement framework based on economic profit that should serve two critical purposes: it will encourage managers to undertake all value-increasing projects (not just those that will maintain or increase reported return on capital), and it will help the companies communicate their strategy and results to the investment community. 相似文献
119.
Nick Cowen 《The Review of Austrian Economics》2018,31(3):373-386
Can John Stuart Mill’s radicalism achieve liberal egalitarian ends? Joseph Persky’s The Political Economy of Progress is a provocative and compelling discussion of Mill’s economic thought. It is also a defense of radical political economy. Providing valuable historical context, Persky traces Mill’s intellectual journey as an outspoken proponent of laissez-faire to a cautious supporter of co-operative socialism. I propose two problems with Persky’s optimistic take on radical social reform. First, demands for substantive equality have led past radicals to endorse exclusionary nationalist and eugenics policies. It pushes some contemporary radicals towards illiberal interventions into intimate social life. Second, the radical critique of capitalism relies on an account of profit that neglects the epistemic function of private-property markets. Once this is acknowledged, capitalism retains some progressive credentials against radical alternatives. 相似文献
120.
Nick Megoran 《Geopolitics》2013,18(2):403-407