全文获取类型
收费全文 | 27188篇 |
免费 | 579篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 5477篇 |
工业经济 | 2022篇 |
计划管理 | 4266篇 |
经济学 | 5907篇 |
综合类 | 638篇 |
运输经济 | 183篇 |
旅游经济 | 422篇 |
贸易经济 | 4195篇 |
农业经济 | 1240篇 |
经济概况 | 3391篇 |
信息产业经济 | 3篇 |
邮电经济 | 23篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 167篇 |
2020年 | 351篇 |
2019年 | 466篇 |
2018年 | 577篇 |
2017年 | 615篇 |
2016年 | 550篇 |
2015年 | 395篇 |
2014年 | 613篇 |
2013年 | 2872篇 |
2012年 | 727篇 |
2011年 | 861篇 |
2010年 | 785篇 |
2009年 | 795篇 |
2008年 | 785篇 |
2007年 | 666篇 |
2006年 | 576篇 |
2005年 | 493篇 |
2004年 | 513篇 |
2003年 | 536篇 |
2002年 | 528篇 |
2001年 | 532篇 |
2000年 | 596篇 |
1999年 | 516篇 |
1998年 | 526篇 |
1997年 | 509篇 |
1996年 | 435篇 |
1995年 | 422篇 |
1994年 | 455篇 |
1993年 | 499篇 |
1992年 | 504篇 |
1991年 | 469篇 |
1990年 | 407篇 |
1989年 | 348篇 |
1988年 | 335篇 |
1987年 | 327篇 |
1986年 | 339篇 |
1985年 | 467篇 |
1984年 | 539篇 |
1983年 | 478篇 |
1982年 | 441篇 |
1981年 | 444篇 |
1980年 | 380篇 |
1979年 | 391篇 |
1978年 | 346篇 |
1977年 | 313篇 |
1976年 | 283篇 |
1975年 | 265篇 |
1974年 | 227篇 |
1973年 | 214篇 |
1972年 | 150篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
41.
We argue that firms with interdependent worker productivity, team production, have a higher cost of absence and, as a consequence, spend additional resources on monitoring absence. As a result, firms with team production should have lower absence rates. We estimate the determinants of absence for blue‐collar workers using a sample of German manufacturing establishments. Workplace teams are used as a proxy for team production. The estimates reveal that firms with teams have lower absence rates, as do smaller establishments. The size effect, however, is unique to establishments with teams, which fits prior theoretical work that has not been previously tested. 相似文献
42.
Using Turkish industry-level data from 1983 to 1990, we find that politically organized industries receive both higher protection and promotion than unorganized ones. Tariff rates are decreasing (increasing) in the import-penetration ratio and the absolute value of the import-demandelasticity for organized (unorganized) industries. Subsidy rates are decreasing (increasing) in the output-supply elasticity for organized (unorganized) industries. The results are consistent with the predictions of the Grossman–Helpman model and its extension in this paper. The mix of protection and promotion is inversely related to the ratio of their respective marginal deadweight cost measures. 相似文献
43.
Thomas D. Willett Aida Budiman Arthur Denzau Gab-Je Jo Cesar Ramos John Thomas 《The World Economy》2004,27(1):25-44
Various claims have been made about the causes of the Asian crisis and its spread. Here, we use data on the behaviour of capital flows during the crisis to test the strong forms of four such hypotheses, that portfolio investors and hedge funds played a dominant role in initiating and/or spreading the crisis; that moral hazard kept efficient markets from predicting the crisis; and, finally, the common lender hypothesis of Kaminsky and Reinhart. In the process we also test implications of the Calvo-Mendoza model of rational investor ignorance. All are falsified as monocausal explanations. For example, portfolio investments that could not have been subject to substantial moral hazard continued to flow into Asia until very shortly before the crisis. Likewise, banks were a much larger source of capital outflows during the crisis than were portfolio investors. While falsified in their strongest forms, several of these hypotheses in less strong forms should play a role in a more nuanced analysis. It is necessary to move past simple single-factor approaches in order to produce a more complete, synthetic explanation of this episode. 相似文献
44.
This study examines how two dimensions of strategic orientation (customer and competitor orientation) influence logistics and market performance. Two capabilities, operational flexibility and collaboration, are studied. Data were collected from manufacturers working with third party logistics providers. The findings suggest that customer and competitor orientations have different influences upon performance when leveraged through the capabilities. Competitor orientation, while having a detrimental direct effect on logistics performance, appears to be the better strategic approach, when supported with operational flexibility since it results in enhanced logistics (efficiency) and market (effectiveness) performance. Customer orientation, on the other hand, greatly improves logistics performance, i.e., internal efficiency. 相似文献
45.
Several papers have been published demonstrating the positive effects a single, reputable ally has on evaluations of a focal brand. Interestingly, little research has been published examining the effects of multiple brand allies. We examine the effect of an alliance with two, one, or zero well-known brand allies on evaluations of a previously unknown focal brand. The presence of a single brand ally significantly increased perceived quality and hedonic and utilitarian attitudes. While multiple alliances improved focal brand evaluations relative to the no ally condition, the second ally did not increase evaluations relative to the single ally condition. 相似文献
46.
47.
48.
The notion that prices impound a wide array of information, including market expectations, has led to earnings forecast models conditioned on prices. Yet, presumably, analysts' forecasts capture both public information and certain private information not previously impounded in prices. Accordingly, price-based models are seemingly an inefficient, and less effective, source of expecta-tions. This article investigates this hypothesis using financial analysts', price-based, and naive forecasts. Results indicate that analysts' forecasts (1) are at least as accurate as price-based and naive models, and (2) yield better expectations for market tests relating returns and earnings. These inferences are robust across different information environments. The evidence suggests that analysts either possess private information or are more effective information processors, or both. 相似文献
49.
In this paper we investigate the use of the structured full rank model for hedging the balance sheet of a financial institution. Simulation results suggest that the optimal hedge is insensitive to changes in parameter estimates. In addition, we hedge a portfolio of Treasury bills using both the full information covariance matrix and the structured covariance matrix. We then contrast these results with those obtained from a duration-based model. Empirical results suggest that the structured full rank model is generally more effective in hedging applications than either the full information model or duration-based model. 相似文献
50.
Milton D. Rosenau 《Journal of Product Innovation Management》1992,9(4):300-302
Too often companies fall into a trap when developing a list of performance specifications for a new product. Milton Rosenau calls this the best-of-the-best specification trap. The problem arises whenever a company bases a specification on the combination of the best single features observed in available competitive products. When this happens, the new product's design is driven by competition and is not derived from a unique market insight. This may not provide the basis for a sustainable advantage. Sometimes, rumors of competitive improvements may even lead to sudden changes in the specification, creating delays in the development process. A far better goal is to develop a specification that responds to an unrecognized and unfilled user need, one that adds high value to users. His points are illustrated with several examples. 相似文献